New Forms and Strategies of the Working Class Movement and Resistance in the Era of Globalization

(Main paper presented in 2nd Arvind Memorial Seminar in Gorakhpur)

Abhinav Sinha

 

1. Introduction

Indian as well as the International working class movement is facing a grave crisis today. Now it is not a matter of contention that the power of capital has dominated the power of labour ever since the fall of the workers’ states in the Soviet Union in 1953 and China in 1976. Nevertheless, capitalism itself has not been able to overcome its own crisis since the 1970s. Right since the economic crisis of 1973, World Capitalism has not witnessed a single phase of significant boom. But owing to the policies of Globalization, the Information Technology and Communication Revolution and the ideological, political and cultural onslaughts on the working class, which was already scattered and somewhat demoralized; the capitalist system, despite its tattered state, has succeeded in preventing any meaningful resistance from the working class and also in keeping it from being organized. In this era of Globalization, the working class movement of India as well as of the world is in crisis today.

Abhinav presenting his paper

Abhinav presenting his paper

Here we would like to clarify a possible confusion at the very outset. When we talk of the crisis of the labour movement, we certainly do not mean that the ideology, science and the world outlook of the working class is in crisis. The attacks unleashed by the capitalist thinkers, ideologues and economists on Marxism-Leninism-Maoism right since the latter half of the 20th century cannot claim any kind of novelty. Most of these attacks had already been answered in the time of Marx and Engels themselves and the remaining were dashed by Lenin. The World Capitalism in its extremely moribund and decaying state has given birth to some new ideological trends since the decade of 1960s (which, it is worthy to note, was the period of the conclusion of the last boom of World Capitalism) which have been termed as Post-Modernism, Post-Colonial Theory, Post-Structuralism etc. The Marxist-Leninist revolutionaries from around the world as well as other Marxist intellectuals have already torn apart these theories and proved that there is nothing new in them. It is nothing but an ugliest possible mixture of the anti-humanitarianism of Nietzsche and Spengler, Anarchism, Kant’s Agnosticism, Russian Nihilism, the theories of post-industrial society and the anti-human absurdities of the computer age.  Our purpose here is not to go into the critical examination of these theoretical tendencies. Moreover, it is a topic which calls for a separate dedicated discussion for itself.

Abhinav presenting paper

Abhinav presenting paper

Therefore, there is no question of the Marxist ideology and science being in crisis. We consider it imperative to clarify this here because owing to their sense of defeatism, poor study, neo-leftist deviations, political nouveau-riche, axis-less free-thinking and frustration, some revolutionary groups and free-thinkers are nowadays bragging about the crisis in Marxist ideology itself and to borrow from French Marxist thinker Louis Althusser, have gone on a “philosophical vocation” for dealing with this crisis (Lenin and philosophy and other essays). Since this crisis-fetishism is particularly in vogue nowadays, we deem it as essential to clarify that we do not believe that the Marxist ideology is faced with any crisis. Of course, every science faces some problems for its purpose is to study the ever-changing world and to search for the laws of its motion. Such problems are the problems of explaining the new phenomena and thereby developing and enriching the science even further. But this is quite natural. Only a dead ideology or religion has the privilege of not facing this problem. Such problems arise only in the realm of science. It would not be an exaggeration to suggest that precisely these are the very problems which constitute the prime mover of any science.

The crisis that we are talking about is the crisis of the working class movement. The working class movement today is faced with a crisis as a result of the strategies adopted by capital for breaking the resistance of labour at the international level in the era of Globalization and for maintaining the falling rate of profit to the level of survival and our purpose is to understand this crisis so that it can be overcome.

We can talk mainly about two aspects of this crisis. One aspect is subjective, which cannot be discussed at length here. This is the crisis constituted by a dogmatic outlook on the plane of programme among the Marxist-Leninist revolutionaries worldwide and particularly in the countries which were termed by Lenin as the weak links of World Capitalism. In our opinion, the programme of the New Democratic Revolution in the camp of Marxist-Leninist revolutionaries worldwide has become a knot, or an albatross round the neck. It requires a critical rethinking with utmost seriousness. The tendency of sticking to the general line given by the Chinese Communist Party led by Mao in 1963, instead of undertaking an original and independent Marxist study of the socio-economic structure, production relations and the level of development of productive forces in one’s own country, has caused tremendous damage to the labour movement.

The labour movement of our country has suffered the loss caused by this dogmatism in two ways. One section of the revolutionary Communists implementing the programme of the New Democratic Revolution does not have any coherent understanding regarding political work in the working class; there are other revolutionary groups who do not think beyond the resolution of the Peasant Question and they do not even have a reach to the working class. The activities carried on by yet another kind of groups in the name of working among the proletariat can at best be called militant economism. Leaving aside some random and scattered efforts, the working class of India has been left at the mercy of the fascist or parliamentary leftist and revisionist trade unions. Consequently, tendencies like trade-unionism, economism and anarcho-syndicalism have entrenched themselves in the working class. This is not a trivial problem. Lenin has clearly stated that economism and anarchism always perpetuates the capitalist pecuniary logic among the workers. It means that the working class remains preoccupied with the battles for wages and allowances. It severely breaks its organization. If these economic battles are made the ultimate goal, the laws of capitalist political economy would become effective among the working class. The logic of competition would work amongst them, which is the most dangerous thing for the working class. Marx and Lenin have stated that the capitalist class organizes spontaneously by means of the average rate of profit. Their organization is born out of the logic of competition. In the capitalist system, one worker is not indispensable for the capitalist because a huge ‘reserve army’ of unemployed workers always remains available in the society. But he cannot do anything without the working class as a whole. Therefore, the power of the workers lies in their being organized as a class and Lenin has written that it needs to be organized in a conscious manner. Spontaneously, the working class acts on the pecuniary logic. The ideology of political organization always comes to them from the outside. This task can only be accomplished by advancing in the direction of party building through a revolutionary political workers’ newspaper. On the other hand, trade union is a special mass organization in which there is no multi-class participation; it is a specific mass organization of the working class. The purpose of a trade union is to unite and organize the working class around its class interests against the onslaught of capital. This is a platform on which the working class learns to organize as a class against capitalism. Regarding the importance of party work within trade union, Lenin has clarified that a Communist organizer carries out a sustained campaign against the tendencies of occupational narrow-mindedness, economism and anarcho-syndicalism and strives for raising trans-regional, trans-factory and trans-occupational class consciousness. It is because of this reason that Lenin has also termed it as the ‘School of Communism’. The Leninist meaning of the Party work within the trade union is the refutation of the pecuniary logic (you can read it economism as well) even while fighting on economic issues; educating and enlightening the working class about its historical mission through party work within the trade union.

Most of the groups belonging to what is called as Marxist-Leninist camp, owing to their ‘hangover’ with the New Democratic Revolution, do not take up the task of working among the working class seriously and even when they try to do so there is lack of clarity and consistency. Consequently, the huge industrial working class of India is left at the mercy of revisionism or the Fascist corporatism. And the cases in which the Marxist-Leninist organizations do go among the working class, they too, in general, end up practising economism, trade unionism and anarcho-syndicalism. They differ with the revisionist trade unionism only in the sense that their economism is a bit more militant, a bit more radical and a bit more ‘red’. But the understanding of political work among the working class is either absent or extremely undeveloped and weak. And if the game is trade unionism and economism then the revolutionary Communists can never overtake the parliamentary Left in this respect.

The second aspect of the problem is the objective one and this is the main concern of this presentation. This aspect is the problem of understanding the changes in the modus-operandi of Imperialism, the changes in the composition of capital since the 1970s, which have collectively been termed as Globalization. In the era of Globalization, together with the neo-liberal policies, privatization, weakening of regulation, increasingly unhindered international flow of capital, downfall of Fordism, emergence of a fragmented assembly line and flexible labour markets, emergence of a more-or-less integrated financial market, the increasing dominance of finance capital and with the capital becoming more and more parasitic, unproductive and predatory; some important changes have occurred in the entire structure, composition, size and nature of the working class all over the world and particularly in the post-colonial and comparatively less developed capitalist countries of the so-called ‘Third World’. Without understanding these changes we cannot talk of building a working class movement in the 21st century. These are the changes that are collectively termed as informalization, feminization, peripheralization, etc. A gigantic unorganized working class has come into being at the global level which is working in both organized as well as unorganized sector. Even the revolutionary Communist groups which are active in the working class also, in general, carry a variety of pre-conceived notions, prejudices and biased attitudes towards this informal/unorganized worker population. They consider it as being backward, bereft of class-consciousness or lacking it. However, the empirical studies do not support such notions. Without understanding the whole character, size and nature of this informal/unorganized working class we cannot even think about building a working class movement at the level of entire country. There are several reasons for this claim, which we will discuss in detail later, but as for now, it suffices to say that it constitutes 97 percent of the total proletarian population of India.

After a brief discussion about the changes that have occured in the modus-operandi of the World Capitalism in the era of Globalization and a detailed discussion about the size, nature and character the informal sector, our third aim in this presentation would be to put forward a proposal on the new forms and strategies of organizing the labour movement and resistance in the 21st century in view of these changes. We ourselves are in the process pf working on these forms and strategies and developing an understanding about them; hence this proposal must surely be considered as working proposal. This proposal is open for discussion before all the comrades present here.

2. A Brief history of Imperialism in the post-Second World War period: Globalization of capital, decay of Regulation, Informalization of labour, unprecedented dominance of Finance Capital and deepening terminal Imperialist Economic Crisis

2.1 Imperialism (1870-1945)

Some important changes have occurred in the modus-operandi of the World Capitalism in the post-Second World War phase. Certainly, we are still living in the epoch of Imperialism and proletarian revolutions. Lenin had propounded the theory of Imperialism after an incisive study of the epochal transformations in the structure and modus-operandi of World Capitalism in the latter half of the 19th century and clearly postulated the strategy and general tactics of the proletarian revolution in the era of Imperialism. Based on his study of Imperialism, Lenin elaborated the characteristic features of the World Capitalism in this age. The main features among them were: the export of capital, the emergence of finance capital with the merger of banking capital with industrial capital and its subsequent dominance, the tendency of monopolization and inter-Imperialist rivalry and wars. These characteristics of Imperialism can be seen even today. Lenin had actually carried forward the analysis of capitalism done by Marx.

Marx had hinted towards the globalizing tendency inherent in the very motion of capital in his works like the ‘Manifesto of the Communist Party’, ‘Capital’ and ‘Grundrisse’. Surely, Marx had not used the term ‘Imperialism’ at that time but we can see some hints of Lenin’s theory of Imperialism in Marx’s words. Consider the following words of the ‘Manifesto’:

Exploiting the world market for its profit the bourgeoisie has given a universal character to production and consumption in every country. To the great chagrin of the Reactionists, it has withdrawn the national base from under the feet of industry on which it stood. All old-established national industries have either been destroyed or are being destroyed regularly. They are being replaced by new industries, whose introduction becomes a question of life and death for all civilized nations; by industries that no longer work upon indigenous raw materials, but raw materials drawn from the remotest countries; by industries whose products are consumed, not only at home, but in every corner of the globe. In place of old wants, satisfied by indigenous production, we find new wants, requiring commodities from distant lands and climes. The old local and national seclusion and self-sufficiency has been replaced by all round mutual intercourse, universal inter-dependence. And as in material production, the same phenomenon has occurred in the field of intellectual production as well. The Intellectual works of individual nations have become universal property. National one-sidedness and narrow-mindedness have become more and more impossible, and a world literature is emerging from the numerous national and local literatures. (Page 46-47, ‘Manifesto of the Communist Party’, Progress Publishers, Moscow)”

Marx clearly specifies the globalizing tendency of capital. In Marx’s time, only one out of three forms or moments of capital, namely, the commodity capital was globalized. The finance capital was still in the process of coming into being and was within the national boundaries and the productive capital was also confined within the national boundaries. Consequently, there was a rivalry among the industrial countries for the capture of the world market, which was aimed at ensuring the availability of cheap raw material and market for produced goods. Thus, colonialism was born as a natural expression of the “free trade” capitalism. Using the terminology of the French Marxist Regulation School, we can say that at that time, colonialism and industrial capitalism were the ‘Dominant Regime of Accumulation’ of World Capitalism and the liberal bourgeois state advocating “free trade” was the ‘Dominant Mode of Regulation’.

World Capitalism had to face its first serious crisis in the decade of 1870s. This crisis was the abundance of capital accumulation within the national boundaries. In fact, it was the same crisis of over-production which Marx calls the terminal crisis of capitalism. Due to the plunder of the world in the era of colonialism, the crisis of over-production and abundance of capital came into existence in the advanced industrial capitalist countries. Now, this capital could not be invested productively within national boundaries anymore. Due to this crisis, the working class had to face terrible unemployment, poverty and inflation and this in result gave rise to the great movements of the working class in countries ranging from France, England and other European countries to the USA. The working class launched politically conscious movements on a large scale. But these movements became training schools for the newly-emerging proletariat, which had begun to challenge the power of capital right in its infancy; naturally, these movements could not establish any sustainable proletarian State. After this onslaught of the working class movements and in order to deal with the crisis of the rate of profit declining to dangerous levels, the World Capitalism was forced to make some important changes in its entire modus-operandi. Lenin studied these very changes and termed the emergence of the financial monopoly capitalism as Imperialism. Lenin argued that in this phase, capital required to expand beyond the national boundaries which could have been possible only through the finance capital (i.e. the merger of banking capital with the industrial capital). With the origin of the finance capital there emerged giant banks, joint-stock companies and cartels in Europe. The export of commodity capital was not a new thing being present as it was for a long time, but this era witnessed the export of money capital and it grew to such an extent in the coming two-three decades that it became the general tendency of the era. The entire German industrialization and the building of war machinery could become possible due to British Banks. The British finance capital played an instrumental role in the emergence of the economic might of Germany. Soon it became clear that the finance capital was increasingly playing a decisive role. The increasing dominance of the finance capital was among one of chief characteristics of the era of Imperialism, as argued by Lenin. Lenin clarified in ‘Imperialism: the Highest Stage of Capitalism’ and also in his other writings on Imperialism and the betrayal of the European Social-Democracy (as both were related phenomena) and economic romanticism that in the era of Imperialism, the storm-centre of the revolutions has shifted from the advanced capitalist countries towards the colonial societies. Formulating the national liberation struggles and the role of proletariat in them, Lenin propounded the theory of the proletarian revolution in two stages and saw the national liberation wars as a part of the world proletarian revolution. Lenin’s prediction proved to be more or less correct. When the centre of the revolutionary storms was shifting from the advanced European capitalist countries towards the countries of Asia and Africa, the proletariat accomplished its first successful revolution at the east-west bridge and established the first proletarian State. After this, the national liberation wars and movements took place in the colonial countries all over the world which gave tremendous setbacks to the World Capitalism. Colonialism as a form of modus-vivendi was bidding adieu to history. World Capitalism was also experiencing changes in its leadership. After the emergence of the new imperialist forces and right since the First World War which took place for the capitalist re-division of the world, the British dominance was on wane. The power of the US capitalism was on the rise. With the beginning of the third decade of the 20th century, the dominance of finance capital was established throughout the world, but, industrial capital still constituted a substantial proportion in the overall composition of the capital, though the control of finance capital over it had been established. By this time, the share markets had become the centre of earning financial profits through the trading of shares and speculation. The financial capital of the world had shifted from London to New York stock exchange. The Great Depression began with the collapse of this very stock exchange in October 1929. This crisis was also the same old crisis of over-production and it appeared in the hitherto most dangerous form in the era of the dominance of finance capital.

Due to this crisis and as a result of the fall of the Social Democracy and the failure of the European working class to convert it into a revolutionary opportunity, Fascist reaction took birth in Germany and Italy leading to the rule of the Nazi party in Germany and Fascist party in Italy. The emergence of Fascism in Europe and the crisis of World Capitalism gave birth to the Second World War. The Second World War continued from 1939 to 1945 and it ended with the defeat of the Axis Powers and the victory of Soviet Union over Germany. By the end of this war two camps had clearly emerged. One was the Socialist camp led by the Soviet Union and the other was the capitalist camp led by the United States of America.

In order to establish its hegemony over the ruined European countries after the Second World War the US brought the Marshall Plan in 1947, which was officially known as the ‘European Recovery Program’. Under this program the USA spent around 13 billion US Dollars till 1951 in form of aid for the reconstruction programmes and stabilization of the capitalist States in the European countries. The American finance capital earned huge profit through this plan. Besides, the US hegemony over the world capitalism was now beyond doubt. After the end of the Second World War a new phase of World Capitalism began which is remembered by bourgeois historians and economists with immense nostalgia. This was the period from 1945 till the crisis of 1973, which is also known as the “Golden Era” of capitalism.

2.2 “Golden Era” (1945–1973)

After the Great Depression and the Second World War the bosses of the World Capitalism had understood that if the entire economy is left at the mercy of the motion of the free market and the vagaries of finance capital and speculation, it would prove to be disastrous. John Maynard Keynes acting as a loyal doctor of capitalism had already told that if speculative capital is like a bubble in the stream of productive capital, it may be acceptable; but if the productive capital itself becomes a bubble in the stream of speculative capital, then the situation could grow out of control. To avoid this, Keynes prescribed the solution of the interventionist and “Welfare” state and this prescription was implemented during the period from 1945 to 1973. In this period, capitalism was riding high on reconstruction projects and there were many opportunities for productive investment. After the large scale destruction of productive forces in the Second World War, many possibilities for productive investment had opened up. Besides, the State was running several welfare schemes on a large scale which was providing social security to the unemployed and youth population. One of the reasons for implementing these schemes was the presence of a Socialist camp as well, where unemployment and poverty had been eliminated, unprecedented improvement had been witnessed in the living standard of the entire population and freedom from socio-economic insecurity had been achieved.

The World Capitalism appeared to be flourishing on account of the prosperity of the US capital and the reconstruction after the Second World War. Fordism too came into existence in the US in the decade of 1940s. This name has originated from the name of Henry Ford who was the founder of Ford Motor Company. Ford introduced a new form of production in his company. He stressed on three things in the entire production process so that production could be achieved at an increasingly bigger scale. The first thing was the maximum possible standardization of production. The second thing was the highly advanced division of labour which was executed by the dynamic assembly line. And the third thing was to minimize the role of skilled labour in the entire process of production. At the same time Ford also believed in the Under-consumptionist logic that the crisis of the system would increase if the workers are not given sustainable and considerable wages. These were some of the fundamental elements of Fordism. Fordism remained the dominant regime of accumulation of the World Capitalism in the period from 1945 to 1973. It could reduce the cost of production and maximize the margin of profit. The entire commodity was manufactured in a single factory and these factories used to be huge in size. Ford implemented this model successfully in his company and in the decade of 1940s it spread to the different parts of the capitalist world. In different countries different names also came into existence, e.g. in Japan it was called as F.S.P (Flexible System of Production) or the Japanese Management System. The factory assumed such a massive form for the first time in the era of Fordism. Often, 15 to 20 thousand workers used to work in a single factory. These workers were generally organized in powerful factory unions. The Dominant Mode of Regulation of this era was the “Welfare State”. So long as it remained a “Welfare State”, the capitalist class was successful in avoiding big clashes between capital and labour; in other words, it was possible for the capitalist class to do so at that time. The process of capital accumulation was functioning more or less  satisfactorily and the capitalist world was witnessing one of the best periods of its prosperity. The capitalist State could afford to give some security to the working class in the form of Factory Laws at that time. The labour markets in the entire world were not flexible and were regulated by Labour Laws. One of the reasons behind this was also the pressure of the organized labour movement. And the capitalist class was not so desperately compelled as to ignore this pressure and use repression to establish its absolutist rule. Thus, the ‘shram qanoon’ (labour laws) had not yet been turned into “sharm qanoon” (shameful laws) and they were implemented to some extent.

In this era, the role of the Nation-State was enforcing and direct. Most of the countries were implementing the protectionist policies keeping in mind the interests of their national capital. The flow of capital, though present at the global level, existed along with national barriers and was regulated to a large extent. The Dollar-Gold standard was present which used to ensure stability to this entire apparatus and was its symbol as well. This in itself was a Keynesian instrument. Under this, the value of US Dollar was pegged with the price of gold and dollar was the standard or unit for other currencies. Consequently, it was not possible for any single country to undertake monetary adjustments at its will. There was no economic crisis on the horizon and hence no national economy felt the need for a floating currency and the Dollar-Gold standard provided them with a stability which was essential for Keynesian ‘Welfare’ State.

However, this phase of prosperity came to an end soon. As soon as the next three decades passed, the capital accumulation had started reaching the stage of saturation. It was no longer possible to utilize the excess of capital within national boundaries. The crisis of over-production was once again looming large over capitalism. By the 1970s the rate of profit had stagnated throughout the capitalist world. The motion of capital had started suffocating within the national boundaries. Soon, the crisis reached its zenith. We know it as the Economic Crisis of 1973. The rate of inflation skyrocketed in many advanced capitalist countries. In the US itself this rate went above 12 percent between 1973 and 1974 and by 1975 it reached to the mark of 25 percent. The unemployment rate in the US reached above the 10 percent mark and there was a fall of 4 percent in its Gross Domestic Product which was indicative of a serious recession. The economy of the entire capitalist world was dependent on the US economy to a large extent and soon the crisis spread to the entire capitalist world. Meanwhile, the capitalist world had to face another crisis. Due to the Arab-Israel conflict, the oil producing Arab countries imposed an oil embargo. It led to an oil crisis in 1973. Due to this reason, old friends of the US, including even Japan, started deserting it. Finally, the US foreign minister Henry Kissinger forced Israel to withdraw its troops from Sinai and Golan Heights. Arab countries lifted their Oil embargo. But by then the world capitalist crisis had deepened further. Along with increasing rate of inflation the rate of unemployment had also become uncontrollable. The simultaneous occurrence of the increase in the rate of inflation, decline in investment and increase in the rate of unemployment, was termed as stagflation by the economists. This was the characteristic feature of the recession of the 1970s. But the main reason behind all this was the excess of capital, over-production and the rate of profit going below the minimum level of survival. In order to deal with this crisis, initially United States of America tried to adopt some monetary measures but it was not possible while the Dollar-Gold standard was in force. Consequently, the USA detached itself from the Dollar-Gold standard and converted the dollar into a floating currency so that by changing the exchange rate and through devaluation of its currency, the crisis could be dealt with. But even this did not work. The situation had already grown too grave for such monetary measures. Other countries also started adopting the policy of floating currency but even they had to face failure. Due to the inflexible labour markets, i.e. due to the relative security of the working class arising out of the labour laws, it was not possible to increase the rate of exploitation and thereby maintain the rate of profit above the survival level. So long as the existing dominant regime of accumulation and dominant mode of regulation remained in force, any such attempt would have had to face a powerful organized resistance from the working class.

When all attempts failed, the think-tanks of the capitalist world started looking for structural changes in the entire capitalist system. They started thinking over new strategies and this process lasted for a few years. One faction was talking about a solution within the Keynesian framework while the other faction was advocating for the neo-liberal policies, i.e. privatization on large scale, liberalization, doing away with all the barriers in the flow of capital, throwing away the labour laws into dustbin and making a flexible labour market, abolishing the fixed currency exchange rates, promoting foreign direct investment and doing away with every kind of regulation. Finally the latter faction had its day and with the beginning of the 1980s, the first experiments of the economic policies of Globalization and neo-liberalization commenced in the world.

2.3 From the decade of 1980s till present : the Era of Globalization and the Significant Changes in the Modus-operandi of Capitalism

Before embarking upon a brief discussion of the process of Globalization, it is imperative to draw attention to an important aspect. The period between 1945 and 1973 was the last period of boom for world capitalism. After that, although the policies of Globalization have provided some breathing space to capital for the time being, yet no period of boom has been witnessed. In fact, the very definition of boom has changed. If we look at the total Gross Domestic Product of the world from 1970, we find that leaving aside some exceptional small phases, it has always gone down. In this entire era there has been a mild recession, intermittently surfacing in form of serious crises. Most of these serious crises have come in the period between the collapse of share market in 1987 and the Sovereign Debt Crisis of 2010. And their frequency has been considerable. The Debt Crisis in Mexico and Latin American countries in the decade of 1980s; the financial crisis of 1987; the monetary crisis of India in the decade of 1990; the east Asian monetary crisis of 1997; the crisis after dot-com crash in 2001; the crisis in 2005 after the bursting of the housing bubble; the American sub-prime debt crisis of 2006-2009 and now the Sovereign Debt Crisis of the European countries in 2010. It is noteworthy that we have not even mentioned all the crises. From the decade of 1980s, i.e. after the implementation of the policies of Globalization, the terminal crisis of the capital has deepened further. It has given some breathing space to the capital in bits and pieces; sometimes with the Keynesian instruments, at times with the State intervention and at other times with the stimulus packages. But all these are proving to be futile endeavours and each and every new crisis is proving to be far more serious than the previous one. Indeed, we can say that while Lenin called Imperialism as the highest stage of capitalism, we can call Globalization as the last stage of Imperialism. Despite this fact, if the world capitalist system is still alive today and the Working Class Movement is in shambles then its reason is inherent in the Lenin’s dictum that “politics must take precedence over economics. To argue otherwise is to forget the ABC of Marxism”. In the era of Globalization the World Capitalism has adopted several new strategies to break the resistance of the working class. Moreover, with the collapse of the Socialist camp and the retreat of the forces of labour worldwide, an atmosphere of pessimism and hopelessness has been created. Apart from this, perhaps the most important factor, the dogmatism prevailing among the revolutionary Communists and the tendency of sticking to the old formula instead of undertaking a Marxist analysis of the new circumstances is also acting as a hurdle in the building of a countrywide revolutionary Communist party and advancing the movement of the working class in any single country. But the level of crisis of the World Capitalism can never be measured by the yardstick of the health of the working class movement. The working class movement being in shambles does not mean that the capitalism is growing and flourishing. There is no need to say a lot about the health of world capitalist system. One does not need to go long back; a look at its history in the new millennium reveals that the capitalism is more moribund, hollow and parasitic than ever and it stays only because there is no organized force today to overthrow it. By understanding the policies, processes and the history of Globalization, one can also understand the strategies of the world capital on the basis of which it has succeeded in fragmenting the organization and resistance of the working class.

The main elements of the policies of globalization were privatization, liberalization, doing away with all the barriers in front of the international flow of capital, putting an end to every kind of regulation by curtailing the government expenditure in a big way, making the labour market flexible by relaxing the labour laws, opening flood gates of foreign direct investment, setting up floating exchange rates so that the regulation of capital can be ended, low rates of interest and completely opening the national market. All these policies were collectively termed by the World Bank and IMF as the Structural Adjustment Program (S.A.P.) in the decade of 1980s and they offered to provide loans to the crisis-ridden countries of the “Third World” on the conditions of implementing these policies. Some countries of Latin America and Mexico became the laboratories for the first experiments of the policies of the Structural Adjustment Program. But soon the devastating consequences of these policies came to surface. Abject poverty, unemployment, retrenchments and lockouts, increasing number of the homeless and the socio-economic insecurity led to resentment among the people. In the beginning of the decade of 1990s the condition of the Indian economy also worsened, though India had not adopted the policies of Structural Adjustment till then. The monetary crisis that shook Indian economy was an expression of the reaching of the saturation point of capitalist development within the framework of public sector capitalism. Now it was no more possible for private capitalism to breath under the system of capital accumulation of the public sector. Though Rajeev Gandhi had already begun to call the policies of regulation of private capitalism (for example, the licence regime, etc.) as “impediments in the way of progress”, the task of getting rid of these policies was properly undertaken in 1991 when the Congress Government, under Narsimha Rao’s leadership and under the direction of finance minister and a neoliberal economist Manmohan Singh, a staunch supporter of the policies of World Bank-I.M.F., started to implement the New Economic Policies. Till then, the disastrous results of the policies of Structural Adjustment had become clearly apparent in Mexico, Argentina and some other Latin American countries and the risks of a totally unregulated economy had become sufficiently evident. Therefore countries like India and China, while on the one hand, implemented the policies of Structural Adjustment, on the other, chose the path to remove the shackles of regulation in a long gradual process, rather than in one go. That is one of the reasons, apart from others, why India and China did not meet the fate of Mexico or other countries of Latin America.

After witnessing the results of implementing the policies of neo-liberalism in an uncontrolled fashion, Mexico and other Latin American countries controlled the situation for some time by adopting the policies of regulation. But with the increasing integration with the world economy the tremors of the crisis anywhere in the world started to be felt in every corner. In 1997 the economies of the South-East Asian countries which had been termed as the ‘Asian Tigers’ started floundering due to monetary crisis. For dealing with this crisis, a new avenue of investment in the world market was required, which was for some time provided by the Dot-Com Bubble. It was the era of e-Commerce and e-Business. People made millions over internet itself which was nowhere to be found in reality. Soon this bubble also busted and then for some time the situation was tried to be taken under control by creating a Housing Bubble. But every such surge of the speculation-driven finance capital was giving birth to even more serious crises. The same happened with the Housing Bubble. By 2005, even this got busted. The period of 2006 to 2008 was that of the most serious recession after the recession of 1930s. This recession originated from the financial markets of the USA where the trash of toxic debt had got accumulated and the US banks and the finance institutions spread it to the financial markets all over the world in the form of a special kind of bonds called Collateral Debt Obligation (C.D.O.). The result was a huge worldwide financial crisis. While the world capitalism was trying to overcome this crisis by giving stimulus packages, the Sovereign Debt Crisis began in Greece 2010 which has now engulfed Portugal, Spain and other South European countries.

In this era of Globalization, three important phenomena unfolded which are worthy of consideration for the working class movement. The first phenomenon was to make a flexible labour market by doing away with every kind of regulation of the labour markets through the policies of neo-liberal Globalization. It was meant to snatch away all such legal rights and legal security from the workers which had been providing them some security against the onslaught of capital ranging from recruitment to the working conditions and from minimum wages to the length of the workday. At the same time the existing permanent and formally employed labour population was retrenched on a large scale. Under the new laws and regulations, the workers could not even raise their voices effectively against this. The second phenomenon was the end of Fordism at the global scale. With the sanction of open freedom for the free flow of capital at the global level it became easier for it to roam around the world for the exploitation of raw material and cheap labour. At the same time, it was difficult to properly implement the anti-labour policies so long as the Fordist large scale production was in force and as long as the labour population was organized at large scale at the factory level. Due to this reason also it had become imperative to do away with the modus-operandi of the Fordist production both economically as well as politically. The third big phenomenon was the revolution in the field of information technology and communication-transportation which took place in this era. It speeded up further the free flow of capital as compared to earlier periods. This revolution provided unprecedented momentum to the process of the Globalization of commodities as well as of capital. It accelerated and simplified the movement of capital across national boundaries. The trans-national corporations (T.N.Cs), although were present even before the decade of the 1980s, but their worldwide dominance could be felt especially after the decade of 1980s. Now the capital could roam around without any barrier anywhere in the world in the search of cheap labour and cheap raw material. The Information Technology not only made it easy to break the Fordist production but also made it profitable. Now there was no need to manufacture the entire commodity in one single factory. If Nike gets the cheap labour and cheap raw material for shoe-sole in Indonesia, the cheap labour and raw material for the production of laces in Turkey, the cheap labour and raw material for the leather body in Mexico, and the cheap labour skilled in assembling all these separate parts in Brazil then it would set up four factories instead of one. The reason being the transportation and communication have become so cheap and fast that the minor increase in the cost of production because of this is far exceeded by the profit earned by exploiting the cheap labour and cheap raw material in different places. On the top of that, nobody bothers about any kind of labour laws in these countries and all sorts of headache can be avoided by getting the work done on contract and sub-contract. An additional and substantially bigger gain is that when the work is done in this manner, the capitalist is freed from troubles of the union etc. as well.

These three changes have done large scale informalization of the entire productive economy in the entire world and particularly the relatively backward capitalist countries of the “Third World” in the last three decades. The informalization of labour means deprive the workers of a permanent and secured wage employment and put them into the ranks of the casual workers, daily wagers and contract workers. This working class population is much more insecure, readier to do work at low wages and more unorganized. It enables the already crisis-ridden capital to increase its rate of profit a little bit. There are two aspects of the informalization of the economy. One is the informalization of the workers’ population which we just mentioned. The second is coming into being of a big informal sector. It means the coming into being of such workshops, factories etc. on a large scale which are either so small that legally they do not even come under the Factory Act (in India 10 labourers with electricity connection or 20 labourers without electricity connection) and therefore fall outside the purview of the state regulation; or such factories which though legally should come under the purview of the Factory Act, but they run illegally without licence and regulation and are exploiting the workers ignoring all the laws. Now we will focus on the size, history and nature of this process of informalization.

3. Informalization: How Much and of What Kind?

3.1 What is informalization?

While discussing about informalization when we say that with the 1970s the Fordist mass production has declined and the integrated assembly line has been fragmented, it surely does not mean that the assembly line itself has vanished and now the production is not carried out on the assembly line. There is a particular reason for giving this clarification. When we said this for the first time, some impatient critiques quoted us in such a way as to mean this and deduced the inference out of the context; and then erected an effigy and rained it with their arrows and alleged that we were saying that now the working class has been deprived of its infallible weapon of halting the production itself! Whereas, what we were saying is merely this: with the old methods, the use of this infallible weapon is getting increasingly difficult and we need to devise other ways and strategies for its use! We would like to clarify this point at the outset so that no such confusion prevails this time around. The fragmentation of the assembly line does not mean that the assembly line itself has come to an end. It also does not mean that the production is carried out on a smaller scale. On the contrary, it means that the production is still carried out on a large scale, rather, one can say, on an even larger scale than earlier. The large scale production is not measured by the size of the floor of the factory. The large scale production is measured by the magnitude of investment and the size of its production. It would amount to political and economic naivety to say that the production is now carried out on a smaller scale, merely because of the fact that the dominant form of accumulation has changed from the production on an integrated assembly line to the one on a fragmented global assembly line. It only means that the production process does not get completed at the level of a single factory; instead, it is done in many factories as required by the different conditions of the availability of cheap labour and raw material for the production of different parts of the commodity, which are, in many cases, geographically scattered not only in one country but in many countries in this era of Globalization.

This process of informalization has two components. The first is the coming into existence of a huge informal sector in the economy. It means the emergence of such industrial units in huge numbers which do not come under the purview of any law or any kind of regulation implemented by the government. These include enterprises ranging from work done at home under subcontracting to handicraft industries, small workshops and small factories. 98 percent of the labour population working in these enterprises does not have a permanent employment with a fixed wage and does not get any kind of legal protection.

The second aspect of this process of informalization is the informalization of the work force of the factories in both organized and unorganized sector. That is, reduction in the size of the workers’ population working in the organized sector on permanent roll and regular fixed wages, through contracting-subcontracting and retrenchment. This in turn means continuously increasing the proportion of the workers working under informal contract even in the organized sector.

Let us see as to how this process is defined by the different government sources and labour historians and economists.

In 2006, the United Progressive Alliance government formed a ‘National Commission on the Enterprises in the Unorganized Sector’ under the chairmanship of Arjun Sengupta. The definition formulated by this Commission can well be considered an accurate definition. This Commission distinguished between the informal sector and informal working class and it is necessary to understand this. Let us see as to how this commission defines these two concepts:

“The informal sector consists of all unincorporated private enterprises owned by individuals or households engaged in the same and production of goods and services operated on a proprietary or partnership basis and with less than ten workers.” (Chapter 2, NCEUS, Report on Definitional and Statistical Issues Relating to the Informal Economy, Government of India, December 2008, New Delhi)

Undoubtedly, around 98 percent population working in such kinds of enterprises work as informal labourers which does not enjoy any employment security, social security, protection of labour laws, decent conditions of work, minimum wages, work day of 8 hours, pension, E.S.I. etc.  But this Commission lays particular emphasis on the fact that today even in the formal/organized sector, more than two-third of the workers’ population has been converted into informal workers, the main reason for which is the process of contractualization, casualization and emergence of the dominance of daily wager system which has been continuing since the last three decades. Therefore, the entire informal working class requires a separate and complete definition. This Commission defines the informal working class as follows:

“Unorganized/informal workers consist of those working in the informal sector or households, excluding regular workers with social security benefits provided by the employers and the workers in the formal sector without any employment and social security benefits provided by the employers.” (ibid.)

It is clear that the informal working class not only consists of the labour population working in the informal sector, but it also includes the population working in the formal sector which has become the victim of contractualization, casualization and work on daily wages.

There is a separate definition of the unorganized working population which was given by the National Labour Commission of 1969 which is as follows: “those who are unable to organize themselves in order to achieve a common aim.” Such population normally consists of those very workers who belong to the informal working class but still there is a difference in the two concepts. Famous economist K.P. Kanan has approved the distinction made by the Arjun Sengupta Commission and has mentioned that today it is important to stress upon the concept of class rather than that of sector. (page 4-6, Dualism, Informality and Social Inequality : An Informal Economy Perspective of the Challenge of Inclusive Development in India, The Indian Journal of Labour Economics, Volume 52, Number 1, January-March,2009). Now let us briefly discuss the categories of formal/informal and organized/unorganized. The formal sector means all the industrial and commercial units coming under the government regulation through factory legislation; the informal sector means the industrial and commercial units where less than 10 workers work and which have an electricity connection or less than 20 workers work and there is no electricity connection. The organized workers’ population refers to the one which is in any way organized in form of a union or organization and which could fight for its economic interests. Unorganized population is the one which is not united or organized in the form of a union or an organization. If we talk of the informal working class instead of informal sector then it would have more or less the same meaning as that of the unorganized working class. But if, we talk about organized working class, instead of formal sector, then it would not mean the same thing as the formal working class. This is because a large part of the formal working class is also unorganized.

Although these are government definitions, however, they cannot be written off just by calling them as governmental because they correctly capture the present realities to a great extent. Their conclusions are different but not the information and the data. Their conclusion is Welfarism and the so-called “inclusive development” within the framework of capitalism and the conclusion that we derive is revolution!

Now, having a glance on the definitions of some non-governmental labour historians and economists would further clarify the concept of informalization.

Among the scholars who have worked on the informal sector and informal working class in India, Barbara Harris-White and Nandini Gooptu and Jan Breman are considered distinguished. Barbara Harris-White and Nandini Gooptu have given the definition of the informalization as follows:

“‘Organized sector labour’ means workers on regular wages or salaries, in registered firms and with access to the state social security system and its framework of labour law. The rest — 93% of the labour force — works in what is known as the ‘unorganized’ or ‘informal’ economy. Unorganized firms are supposed to be small. In fact they may have substantial work-force, occasionally numbering hundreds, but where workers are put deliberately on casual contracts.” (Page 89, Mapping India’s World of Unorganized Labour, Working Classes, Global Realities, Socialist Register, 2001)

The study of Harris-White and Gooptu tells us that the informalization has incessantly been pushed ahead through three processes: contractualization or sub-contractualization, ‘Putting out system’ and casualization. Even the government statistics confirm the objectivity of this observation. The ‘putting out system’ which has come into being in today’s time is not the same institution which originated in the medieval period. Today, the jobs given under the ‘putting out system’ are performed by thousands of families on piece-rate basis in their respective households, for example, jobs ranging from bidi-making, bangle-making to the manufacture of spare parts to be used in the automobile and construction industry. These domestic enterprises are part of the huge circuit of capital. Lenin has clearly written about them, whom we will quote later in this paper while discussing about the nature and character of the informal working population.

Jan Breman is the leading historian who has undertaken the study of the informal sector in India. Breman has written many well-known books and articles on the topic and the credit for bringing the informal working class to the centre of study among the Indian Marxist academicians must go to Breman primarily. Breman, while doing a dialectical analysis of this entire phenomenon and searching for the origins of the informalization, writes that from the 1970s due to the change in the land relations and from the period of ‘Green Revolution’, the migration of the labourers from rural areas to urban areas increased with unprecedented rapidity. These migrant labourers, millions in numbers, could not succeed in getting a permanent and regular job and continued to be accumulated in the ‘surplus’ labour pool of the cities. The capital always utilizes this entire pool for increasing its profit and after the implementation of the neo-liberal policies from the decade of 1980s, this was done at the global level and in India this process unfolded especially from the decade of 1990s. Breman argues that the terms informal sector and informal workers’ population was first mentioned by a Marxist anthropologist named Keith Hart in 1973 in his study about Ghana. In this study, Keith Hart argues, while mentioning the scene of the streets of cities of Ghana that along with the advance of capitalist development, the scene of the streets started changing. A huge colourful crowd could now be seen which included numerous workers doing petty jobs –shoe-polishers, street vendors, pedlars, tinkers, etc. (Informal Income Opportunities and Urban Employment in Ghana, Journal of Modern African Studies, 11, 1: page 61-89,1973)

Breman argues further that the emergence of such an informal economy was quite natural in the Indian capitalist development or, for that matter, in the type of development which took place in all countries which became independent between 1950 and 1980. This was not a backward, pre-modern, primitive working class. The internal mobility within this entire class was so high that it could be considered a worker in a factory, as well as a street side vendor, pedlar, rickshaw-puller and a farm labourer! Because often he/she used to do all these works in a single year! In such a scenario, to call him backward or primordial is a prejudice. Also, it is not as if he is not skilled. In fact, he is multi-skilled. We will come back to the opinions which have been put forward by Breman on the nature of this working population.

Famous labour historian Prabhu Mahapatra writes that the origin of the informal sector could be seen even in the colonial capitalist system. Mahapatra finds it incorrect to consider the informal sector as beyond regulation. According to him the informality of both the class and the sector has been regulated right from the beginning. True, this regulation is not imposed through clear and direct laws. Capitalism has always required the informal sector and it regulates it through means other than laws. Mahapatra states that Marx clearly showed that the capital regulates the labour not only through its state power but through the private informal means as well. Hence informalization is not something which has arisen out of some kind of aberration of the capitalist system. It has always remained an integral part of the modus-operandi of the capital. Informality can be considered as the lack of formal regulation but not lack of regulation itself. (see Marx, the chapter pertaining to the factory laws in Capital, Volume-I).(page 29-46, Making of the Coolie: Legal construction of Labour relations in colonial India and in the Caribbean, Labour in the Public Arena , V.V. Giri National Labour institute, Noida 2004)

Similarly there are numerous labour historians and economists like Geert De Neve, Dilip Simeon, Rohini Hensmann, Arjan de Haan etc., who have given definitions of the informal sector and informal working population. For their writings you can refer to the bibliographical section in the end.

Later, we will also briefly discuss the ways in which Marx and Lenin viewed the informal working class (though they never used this term).

3.2 Informal working class: number, size and its region-wise distribution

Why is it that the informal working class today has become an important and a central question for the Indian working class movement? The plain and clear answer to this question is this: it constitutes 93 percent of the total working class population! The situation becomes even clearer by having a glance at the sectoral and region-wise distribution of the informal/unorganized working class, apart from its size and number.

The total working class population today is about 45.8 crore. It does not include the poor and marginal peasant population. It is purely the rural and urban proletariat population. 93 percent of this population consists of the informal/unorganized workers’ population working in the informal sector. Remaining 7 percent population works in the formal sector, three-fourth of which are the contract, daily wage or casual labourers, and even when they are permanent, they are not organized in any union in most of the cases. Even of the 3 percent that is organized in unions, the majority has become disenchanted from the revisionist and fascist trade union bureaucracy. The still remaining does not even consider themselves as workers. To a large extent this remaining section can be counted as part of what Lenin called labour aristocracy. It is not without reason that recently the fascist Bhartiya Mazdoor Sangh (BMS) has become the biggest trade union surpassing CITU. It alludes to the important changes which the structure and nature of this 3 percent labour population has undergone. Jan Breman writes somewhere: “In the landscape of labour, industrial workers in the organized sector of the economy form a privileged and protected enclave. …In addition to their secure employment status, they constitute an ‘aristocracy’ with a high social profile and a reasonably comfortable lifestyle”. (page 407, The study of industrial labour in post-colonial India — The informal sector: A concluding review, The Worlds of Indian Industrial Labour, Sage Publications, 1999). Anyway, let’s return to the principal issue. In all, 97 percent workers belong to the informal/unorganized working class (including both, in the formal as well as the informal sectors).

Barbara Harris-White and Nandini Gooptu inform us that the 7 percent formal labour population earns around 34 percent of the total wages while the 93 percent informal/unorganized labour population only manage to get 66 percent share. Between 1977 and 1994 the growth rate of informal economy was 2.6 percent whereas, that of the formal sector was around 1 percent. A large part of the labour population of the unorganized sector works at their homes. A considerably large part this labour population is the one which works at its home with family labour, as a part of the fragmented assembly line. Following Lenin, Jan Breman believes that this population should be considered as wage labour. Lenin termed it as the ‘outside department’ of the industry. Harris-White and Gooptu also agree on this. The labourers working at home are included in the ‘self-employed’ population in the government statistics which is illusory and misleading. Moreover, it relieves the State of its responsibilities. This category has been invented for this very purpose. Lenin has considered it as an illusory and misleading category. These so called ‘self-employed’ workers constitute 56 percent of the total workers’ population. The share of the casual labourers in the total working class population is 29 percent. (All the above statistics are from this source: Barbara Harris-White and Nandini Gooptu, Mapping India’s World of Unorganized Labour, Working classes, Global Realities, Socialist Register, 2001). 60 percent of the Gross National Product of the country, 68 percent of the Total Income, 60 percent of Total Savings, 31 percent of the Total Agricultural Export and 41 percent of the Total Industrial Export comes from informal sector (India’s Socially Regulated Economy, Barbara Harris-White, Critical Quest, New Delhi, 2007).

The statistics of the report of Arjun Sengupta Commission has clarified the picture of the workers of unorganized/informal sector in the most commendable ways. This report mentions that if the Indian economy grows with the rate of 7 percent in 2011-12, the total proletarian population would be 54 crore (which does not include the semi-proletarian poor peasants which is standing on the verge of ruination and whose population is between 25 and 30 crore). 47 crore of such workers would be in the informal sector and merely 7 crore in the formal sector. This report states that currently only 17.3 percent of the total industrial production is being carried out by the formal workers’ population, while the informal workers’ population is responsible for 82.7 percent of industrial production. In 1990 among all the manufacturing units, 52 percent were such in which less than 50 labourers used to work. It is noteworthy that the real process of informalization actually began in 1990. Now one can easily simulate the present condition.

After the Arjun Sengupta Commission, if any other source presents the clearest picture of informalization, it is the statistics of the National Sample Survey Organization. In 2000-2001, the 55th round of the sample survey was conducted. According to this, at that time the working population (rural and urban) was 40 crore, out of which 34.3 crore was in the informal sector. 67.7 percent of this informal workers’ population was agricultural labourers and 32.3 percent was constituted by non-agricultural labourers (including industrial). So the total informal labour population constituted 91 percent of the total labour population. (National Sample Survey, 55th round, National Sample Survey Organization). 3 years later, the statistics which appeared in the 61st round reveal a lot about the pace of informalization. According to this, there were 45.8 crore workers (rural and urban) in the country. Around 39.5 crore among them were informal labourers. 64 percent of the total informal labourers were agricultural labourers and 36 percent non-agricultural labourers. The total proportion of the informal labourers shot up to 93 percent. It needs to be kept in mind that this data is that of 2004. (National Sample Survey, 61st round, National Sample Survey Organization). If we assume that in the last 6 years the pace of informalization increased with the same rate, then today the informal working class population would be around 96 percent of the total working class population and the total working class population would be around 53 crore. That implies that the informal working class population itself would be around 47 crore. 20 crore among them would be those who are involved in industrial production.

These statistics present a clear picture of the size, number and distribution of the informal/unorganized labour population to a great extent. There are a lot of such statistics which confirm this basic trend. Here, it is not necessary to present all of them. The above statistics are sufficient to make it clear that the sheer size of the informal/unorganized working class population is such, that to ignore it, you have to be a blind person. This question stands as one of the principal questions on the agenda of the entire working class movement today as to how this huge population, which has been termed by the famous Marxist writer Mike Davis as “the fastest growing and the most unprecedented social class on earth” (Planet of Slums, Verso, 2006), can be organized? What are the challenges of organizing them? Does today’s informal/unorganized worker possess a backward consciousness? Does he possess a peasant consciousness? Is he pre-modern? Is he primitive? Does he lack class consciousness? If somebody believes so, does he/she have any analysis to support his/her belief? If someone does not believe so, what kind of analysis does he/she have? This brings us to the third issue related to the informal/unorganized working class – what is the nature and character of the informal working class population? We will discuss this important issue in the light of the views of Marx and Lenin and we will also analyze the historical and statistical-empirical studies of the contemporary Marxist historians and economists.

3.3 Informal/unorganized Working Class: Nature, Character and Consciousness

The first characteristic of the informal working class which comes to our attention is its being geographically scattered in terms of the workplace. So far as the factory floor is concerned, this population is in the process of being dispersed. We have already explained the reason for this process of dispersion. At the national level the number of big factories has declined considerably. If we leave aside the core sector, almost entire industrial activity is going into the informal sector. (Globalization and Labour, Naveen Chandra, the speech delivered at the Dr. Ramnadham Memorial Meeting organized by PUDR in Delhi). Even in the big factories which are still existing and in the industrial centres in which some big factories are being set up (although it is not a common trend), a large proportion of the working population (leaving aside the technicians and foremen) is employed on the basis of daily-wages or contract or they work as casual labourers. The most important characteristic of this population is that it is extremely mobile. Even among the workers who work on contract, daily wages or work as casual labourer in the bigger factories, the tendency of sticking to a single factory diminishes to a large extent. Therefore, it becomes a challenging task to form a powerful trade union in these factories. The reason is the extremely high internal mobility of the target population. Today, for the workers working in a big factory, it is most likely that 50 percent among them would be replaced in the next six months. And one organizes individuals, and not the numbers, in the unions. Thus, may be the number of the workers working in a factory remains the same or may even increase, but its profile is changed. Jan Breman, in one of his famous and widely acclaimed work – Footloose Labour: Working in India’s Informal Economy, 1996, Cambridge University Press – has termed this volatile labour population as Footloose labour, i.e., as if the worker has got some wheel attached to himself/herself and who keeps on changing his/her job due to the lack of any kind of job security or social security. It was because of this reason that Jan Breman also called them as wage hunters and gatherers (Wage Hunters and Gatherers: Search for Work in the Urban and Rural Economy of South Gujarat, 1994, Oxford University Press, Delhi) which is quite an appropriate term for an informal worker. The high workplace mobility of this labourer makes it extremely difficult to find him/her and mobilize-organize him/her at his/her workplace. This labourer is normally a multi-skilled labourer who would generally have worked in the industries ranging from primitive to advanced, done the so called ‘self-employed’ work, worked at his home with the family labour, also done the works like rickshaw-pulling, street-side vending or have worked as pedlar. And, often he/she has done all of these works within a single year and may be has also worked as agricultural labourer for three months in the countryside.

Jan Breman believes that a large part of the 56 percent so-called ‘self-employed’ population is actually wage labourer and is part of the industrial world itself. In real terms, the ‘self-employed’ is that population which in the language of economics is known as the so-called ‘own account’ entrepreneur. The number of such entrepreneurs would not be even 5 percent of the total informal industrial labour population. According to Breman, the proletarian consciousness of the working class cannot be grasped in a mechanical way by fitting into the old formulae. While rebutting another Marxist intellectual Tom Brass in a debate on the bonded labour among the rural informal workers, he said that being “un-free” in such a manner cannot be seen as a lack of the capitalist development and proletarian consciousness. It would be a grave mistake to apply the Marxist concept of the free and the “un-free” labour so mechanically. On the basis of his study in Gujarat, Breman explains that the informal labour population in no way lags behind the permanent factory labourers in terms of class consciousness. And we would take this opportunity to add that from their conditions of life itself they are more anti-system.

Marxist thinker Henry Bernstein has also supported this argument. Following the works of Jan Breman and Mike Davis on the informal working class, Bernstein explains that today’s informal working class is extremely multi-coloured class in which there is tremendous internal mobility. It is extremely radical class which faces the State-power of the capital right from streets to the home and the work place. There is no lack of class consciousness in it. And from the decade of the 1980s, the kind of policies which are being adopted by the World Capitalism due to its crisis, has produced a huge informal working class in the last thirty years or so, which unlike “surplus” labour population of earlier periods does not suffer from unskilled, backward, peasant or primitive consciousness; on the contrary, this class is radical, modern and equipped with proletarian consciousness. This class is compelled to live in the abject poverty and this very factor is the source of its being radical. Quoting from Mike Davis, Bernstein contends that this is hitherto the fastest growing part of the proletariat, which is huge and brimming with possibilities. (Keynote lecture in the Conference on the topic Lliving on the Margins. Vulnerability, Exclusion and the State in the Informal Economy, Cape Town, 26-28 March, preparatory draft available on the internet)

Famous labour historian Geert  De Neve has done a brilliant study on the textiles industry of Tamil Nadu which sheds light on a number of dimensions of the informal working population. Geert  De Neve  expresses his disagreement with the conclusions of Barbara Harris-White and Nadini Gooptu that there is a lack of skill among the informal working class. On the basis of his exhaustive and intensive study of the power loom industry of Tamil Nadu, De Neve proves the fact with his findings that this informal working class is adequately skilled and in many ways it possesses even more technical skills than the organized working class. De Neve also considers it an oversimplified perception that the industrial units in the informal sector are only of small size. He states that the statistics of the units being smaller is based on the information given to the government agencies by the small capitalist class which is false in more than half of the cases. Certainly there is large number of small industrial units in the informal sector. But on the basis of his studies, he shows us that even the medium and large scale industrial units are not little in numbers in the informal sector; needless to say, most of them are operating illegally. De Neve corroborates Jan Breman and contends that it is a prejudice of the leadership of working class movement towards the informal working class that it suffers from the lack of class consciousness. A variety of studies on the informal sector inform us that in the labourers working in the informal sector, there is considerable class consciousness which is, in many ways, more advanced than that in the labour population working in the organized sector. (page 1-38, Introduction, The Everyday Politics of Labour: Working Lives in India’s Informal Economy, Geert  De Neve, Social Science Press, Delhi, 2005).

To have a glance at the writings of Marx and Lenin after these labour historians and economists, would be instrumental for an understanding of the character of the informal working class.

Marx, while writing about the ‘creation of the relative surplus population’ in the Section III of Chapter XXV of Volume I of Capital, puts forward many such observations before us which are useful for understanding the character of the labour population of today’s informal sector. Marx explains that along with the increasing accumulation of capital, the capitalist increases the constant capital (i.e., investment on technology and machinery) due to which there is an unprecedented increase in the productivity of the variable capital and there is an increase in the rate of production of surplus value. At the same time, the capitalist retrenches the workers with a view to minimize the expenditure incurred on regular basis and thus a relative surplus population is created. Marx shows that in accordance with the different cycles of capital accumulation, the size and nature of this relative surplus population also keep on changing. But with the continued development of capitalism it becomes a permanent feature of the capitalist society and an essential necessity for the capital. Total employment society is an anti-thesis of capitalism. It may happen in a small peculiar phase but it cannot become a general trend of a capitalist society. This relative surplus population manages to survive in the capitalist society by doing this or that work at different times with irregular employment and social insecurity and enhances the capacity of capital to bargain against the employed workers. It acts as the reserve labour army of capital. Marx has described four main types of this relative surplus population : floating, latent, stagnant and pauper. The fourth among them is the one which is not a part of the workforce, e.g., beggars, handicapped, insane etc. But the remaining three are part of the work force. The most important among them are the first and the third ones. About the stagnant relative surplus population, Marx states that it is part of the active work force but it has highly irregular kind of employment. Consider the following quotation of Marx:

“The third category of the relative surplus-population, the stagnant, forms a part of the active labour army, but with extremely irregular employment. Hence it furnishes to capital an inexhaustible reservoir of disposable labour-power. Its conditions of life sink below the average normal level of the working-class; this makes it at once the broad basis of special branches of capitalist exploitation. It is characterised by maximum of working-time, and minimum of wages. We have learnt to know its chief form under the rubric of “domestic industry.” … Its extent grows, as with the extent and energy of accumulation, the creation of a surplus-population advances. But it forms at the same time a self-reproducing and self-perpetuating element of the working-class, taking a proportionally greater part in the general increase of that class than the other elements. (Page 602, Capital, Volume 1, Karl Marx, Progress Publishers, Moscow, 1974 Reprint)

The second big part of the informal labour population today is the one which has been termed by Marx as floating relative surplus population. Following quotation of Marx about it provides another insight about the today’s informal working class:

“In the centres of modern industry — factories, manufactures, iron-works, mines, etc. — the labourers are sometimes repelled, sometimes attracted again in greater masses, the number of those employed increasing on the whole, although in a constantly decreasing proportion to the scale of production. Here the surplus-population exists in the floating form.

In the automatic factories, as in all the great workshops, where machinery enters as a factor, or where only the modern division of labour is carried out, large numbers of boys are employed up to the age of maturity. When this term is once reached, only a very small number continue to find employment in the same branches of industry whilst the majority are regularly discharged. This majority forms an element of the floating surplus-population, growing with the extension of those branches of industry.” (Page 600, ibid.)

Later in the same statement, Marx argues that the tendency of juvenilization and feminization of the workforce is inherent in capitalism. And we were under the impression that the theorization of informalization, feminization of the work force and child labour is to be credited to the 20th century intellectuals! It is clear that Marx in his writing has lucidly portrayed this trend of capital. Now it is a different thing that in the form of a dominant and concretely expressed phenomenon, it has emerged in the era of Globalization.

Marx while mentioning about the third type of relative surplus population states that it is a latent relative surplus population which mainly includes the hidden unemployed, irregular agricultural labourers and the rural poor involved in non-agricultural activities. With the penetration of capital into the villages, this population continues to migrate to the cities, at times with slow pace and with rapid pace at other times. (See the entire chapter mentioned above.)

It is quite evident that Marx was pretty clear and certain about the creation of an industrial informal working class, like that of today. It was bound to happen with the natural motion of the capital. It happened earlier too, but in different forms. In the era of Globalization, this phenomenon has appeared in a new form.

Lenin also foresaw the emergence of a such an informal working class when he was studying the development of capitalism in Russia. Although the main objective of this study of Lenin was more to rebut the faulty theories of the Narodniks about the formation of a domestic market and the crisis of the recovery of the surplus value and less to study the emergence of the different parts and components of the proletarian population. But despite that one gets a brilliant insight about the emergence of the informal working class population in this work.

Lenin, while describing about the different stages of the capitalist development in industries, argues that the first stage is that of artisanal production in which the commodity production has not yet fully developed. The characteristics of wage labour in the producer are still negligible. With the separate development of marketing of the product, the task of commercial capital is separated which is an important division of labour from the point of view of the development of industry. With this the artisan continues to get increasingly dependent on the trader in a gradual process, not only in terms of marketing but also in terms of the supply of the raw materials. From here begins the second stage, that is called the “putting out system”. Lenin states that with the passage of time, the relationship between the trader and artisan turns into the one between a capitalist and a wage labourer. It is from here that the commodity production begins with Simple Capitalist Co-operation. But still, every labourer does all kinds of work and the division of labour in the process of production is in embryonic form. Along with the development of the productive forces this simple capitalist cooperation is replaced by complex division of labour and it is at this point that the third stage, i.e. Manufacturing, begins. Along with the stage of manufacturing, the production expands rapidly and with this the market also expands. With the expansion of the market manufacturing reaches such a level of development which, Lenin has written, could almost be considered as the Factory System. In the stage of manufacturing, when the division of labour continues to develop further to reach the level of such separate small activities which could then be automated, the machinery enters into the picture. With this the Factory System comes into being and the industry reaches the stage of machinofacturing from that of manufacturing. Lenin states that in the age of simple commodity production the main form of industry surfaces in the form of domestic industry. In the era of manufacturing the main form of industry is manufactory, which Lenin distinguishes from the factory. And after this the era of factory ensues in which automation brings the industry up to the stage of assembly line production.

Some comrades might well find this discussion unwarranted but it was essential for the whole logic which we intend to elaborate later. Lenin states that these stages should not be divided chronologically. Even in the most advanced capitalism the periods of different stages overlap with each other. Not every time this overlap results in form of the baggage of the past but many a times it occurs as an essential component of the capitalist development. It is here that the key to understand the development and expansion of the informal working class lies. Lenin states that along with the development of the factory system and machinofacturing, a large network of ancillary industries comes up in the vicinity of the factory (today the condition of being in the vicinity is no longer mandatory, Long Live the communication-transportation revolution!). Just consider the following quotation of Lenin:

“But this splitting of production into the simplest operations, while being a necessary preparatory step to the introduction of large-scale machine production, leads at the same time to a growth of small industries. The surrounding population is enabled to perform such detailed operations in its homes, either on the order of the manufactory owners, using their materials, or even “independently” buying the materials, making certain parts of the product and selling them to the manufacturers. It seems paradoxical that the growth of small (sometimes even “independent”) industries should be an expression of the growth of capitalist manufacture: nevertheless, it is a fact. The “independence” of such “handicraftsmen” is quite fictitious. Their work could not be done, and their product would on occasion even have no use-value, if there were no connection with other detailed operations, with other parts of the product. … One of the main errors of Narodnik economics is that it ignores or obscures the fact that the “handicraftsman” performing a single operation is a constituent part of the Capitalist manufactory.” (Page 433-434, The Development of Capitalism in Russia, Lenin, Progress Publishers, Moscow, 1977 Reprint).

This quotation of Lenin to a large extent articulates the reality of the industrial development and the formation of the working class in the post-colonial capitalist societies. Let’s have a look at another quotation:

“In all the industries organized on the lines of manufacture that we have examined, the vast mass of the workers are not independent, are subordinated to capital, and receive only wages, owning neither raw material nor finished product. At bottom, the overwhelming majority of the workers in these “industries” are wage-workers, although this relationship never achieves in manufacture the completeness and purity characteristic of the factory. … Under manufacture, side by side with the mass of dependent workers, there always remains a more or less considerable number of quasi-independent producers. But all this diversity of forms of dependence merely covers up the main feature of manufacture, the fact that the split between the representatives of labour and of capital is already manifested in full force.” (Page 439-440, ibid.)

Later in the same statement, Lenin argues further that in this stage of the development of capitalism there also exist a class of labourers which still lives in the illusion of becoming proprietor, but this illusion is soon shattered into pieces. Have a look at yet another fitting quotation which throws light on the informal aspect of the capitalist development in the post-colonial society:

“This retention (and even, as we have seen above, development) of small establishments under manufacture is quite a natural phenomenon. Under hand production the large establishments have no decisive advantage over the small ones; division of labour, by creating the simplest detailed operations, facilitates the rise of small workshops. For this reason, a typical feature of capitalist manufacture is precisely the small number of relatively large establishments side by side with a considerable number of small establishments. (Page 443, ibid.)

Lenin opines further that in reality these small workshops act as an ‘outside department’ of the big manufacturing units. Lenin also states that in this entire phase while the factory system, manufacturing, small industrial units simultaneously exist, an entire class of contractors and intermediaries comes into existence. And along with this the most brutal form of exploitation comes into existence through this contractualization. The reason for this is that work done at the small industrial units and at home is only a part of the capitalist manufacturing. The following quotation might appear as a prediction of informalization:

“Let us point, first of all, to the multitude of middle-men between the capitalist and the worker in domestic industry. The big entrepreneur cannot himself distribute materials to hundreds and thousands of workers, scattered sometimes in different villages; what is needed is the appearance of middle-men (in some cases even of a hierarchy of middle-men) to take the materials in bulk and distribute them in small quantities. We get a regular sweating system, a system of the severest exploitation: the “subcontractor” (or “workroom owner,” or “tradeswoman” in the lace industry, etc., etc.), who is close to the worker, knows how to take advantage even of specific cases of his distress and devises such methods of exploitation as would be inconceivable in a big establishment…” (page 447, ibid.)

In the same statement Lenin goes on to describe the conditions of work in such industries. If this description is presented before someone without any context, it might appear as the description of the conditions of the work and life of today’s informal sector labourers (see page 447-449, ibid.)

Lenin while comparing the Russian case with the capitalist development of the advanced countries expressed the hope that when the machino-facturing would be advanced enough in Russia, then one could do away with such industries. But the history of the latter half of the 20th century has shown that even after the machino-facturing getting dominant, the capital has further expanded the informal sector in the era of Globalization in order to increase the rate of profit and for dismantling the resistance of the working class. And still it has managed to maintain the productivity. There are many reasons for this. The first reason is that the division of labour today is at a much higher level than that in Lenin’s period and in such a situation the dividing line between the skilled and unskilled labour has been blurred. Lenin himself predicted this. If the entire production process can be fragmented without lowering the level of productivity, it would be beneficial for the capital in the short term. It has also become feasible because the information technology and communication-transportation revolution has enhanced the mobility of the capital to such an extent that the cost for setting up and functioning a fragmented assembly line has become almost negligible. And its benefits exceed its costs because the capital can easily reach the places wherever the cheap labour and cheap raw material for the production of different parts of the product would be available.

At another place Lenin states that in a capitalist society a class of informal/unorganized workers would always be present. At the same time, a huge labour population would be present as an “appendage” to the factory which would include loader-unloaders, construction workers, packers, etc. They would constitute a considerable proportion of the population of the entire working class. (page 539-541,ibid.) This point becomes even more clearly apparent with the following statement of Lenin:

“In order to give anything like a full description of the appendage to the factory one needs complete statistics on the occupations of the population, or monographic descriptions of the entire economic life of factory centres and their environs. But even the fragmentary data with which we have had to contend ourselves show the incorrectness of the opinion widespread here that factory industry is isolated from other forms of industry, that the factory population is isolated from the population not employed in factories. The development of forms of industry, like that of all social relationships in general, cannot but proceed very gradually, among a mass of interlocking, transitional forms and seeming reversions to the past. Thus, the growth of small industries may express (as we have seen) the progress of capitalist manufacture; now we see that the factory, too, may sometimes develop small industries.” (Page 541, ibid.)

In order to elaborate the Marxist logic of the roots of the informalization, it was a Herculean task to select quotations from ‘The Development of Capitalism in Russia’ as their quantity was so huge that the limit of this paper does not allow all of them to be included. We are providing the references of those quotations and the comrades interested in reading the discussions on the origins of informalization in this work can see those portions. For the three main stages of industry, their overlapping and different types of working class coming into existence during these stages and their simultaneous existence, please see page 546-47; For the tremendous internal mobility, seasonal migration, circular migration and non-agricultural migration among the informal working class, please see page 55; for advanced class consciousness of the migrant and urban informal worker, see page 582-87. Especially, the last reference is worth considering.

Now we would like to briefly present before you our conclusions about the informal/unorganized working class population.

Firstly, the emergence of the informal working class is not an aberration of the capitalist development, but a rule. It has been clearly shown both by Marx and Lenin. Lenin has also shown that particularly in those countries where the capitalist development took place late and at a latter point of time, and in particular, through non-revolutionary path, the presence of such a working class was but natural.

Second point, this working class is not backward, not so even in the days of Marx and Engels, not even in Lenin’s era and certainly not today. These are the prejudices created by the trade-unionism which was born in the Fordist era of integrated assembly line and mass production. There is a need to get rid of the prejudices that the informal/unorganized working class possesses backward, primitive, peasant, pre-modern or non-industrial consciousness. If someone carries such an opinion about today’s informal/unorganized working class, he/she is surely unaware about today’s informal working class.

Third point, today’s informal working class is, in general, more radical than those 7 percent workers who are working in the formal/organized sector; it is anti-capitalist from its very nature; it is relatively freer from the economism, anarcho-syndicalism and revisionism spread by the revisionist trade unions; this working class owing to its mobility is also relatively free from the tendencies of occupational narrow-mindedness and it does not consider any single factory owner as its enemy, instead recognizes, and in quite practical terms so, entire class of the factory owners as its enemy. Its politicization is relatively easy, but there is no denying the fact that understanding this logic would be a bit difficult for those whose mind has been ossified within the old trade unionist economistic ways and means.

Fourth point, this class is not only directly confronted with the capitalist class, but everyday from home to streets and to the work place it is also directly confronted with the Government which acts as the managing committee of the capitalist class. This class does not hold any kind of legal illusion regarding the police, bureaucracy, judiciary and the leaders of the bourgeois parties. All these organs of the bourgeois system are exposed on a daily basis in front of this class in the most brutal ways.

Fifth point, Due to the dispersal of the working class on the factory floor and the basis of work place, an immediate pessimism and hopelessness has crept into the psyche of this class and it is finding itself helpless in many ways. The reason for this is that it is not able to think beyond the old forms of resistance by itself and feels that the very ground of carrying out meaningful resistance has been snatched away from under its feet. But new forms of the resistance of the working class have emerged in many workers’ struggles, especially in the Chattisgarh labour movement, the movement of unorganized workers of Delhi in 1988 and recently in the Almond Workers’ movement in Delhi. About the Chattisgarh labour movement a Turkish Marxist intellectual Fatma Ülkü Selçuk wrote in the ‘Monthly Review’ in 2005: (‘Dressing the Wound: Organizing Informal Sector Workers’, May 2005, Monthly Review). This whole article is a brilliant documentation of the new forms of resistance of the informal working class in different parts of the world.

Sixth point, this informal working class is tremendously mobile. The informal/unorganized workers generally do many kinds of works for small durations in a single year due to the lack of job security and thus they become skilled in many trades. You can find a worker who knows the work of masonry and at times works as a construction worker; but at the same time he would also have worked in a factory making iron-sheet, in a factory making spare parts of automobiles, in a factory making pressure cookers or paint of screen printing and in the export garment industry; in the event of none of these works being available, he would work as a street-side vendor or pedlar and in the months of April-July he even goes to Punjab, Western Uttar Pradesh and Haryana to work as an agricultural labourer as well. What we mean to say is that, this working class is highly mobile in terms of work place.  This fact is confirmed by almost all historians and economists studying the workers of the informal sector and also by the statistics of Census, National Sample Survey and National Rural Labour Commission.

Seventh point, the presence of the traditional trade unions is relatively negligible among the informal working class. In fact, the presence of any type of political force is sparse among them. And wherever some trade unions are raising some issues of these workers, they are not very important for them and in most of the cases the traditional trade unions utilize the numerical strength of these workers for strengthening their own movements and demonstrations whose main purpose is to fight for the economic demands of mainly organized workers’ population. In such a scenario, there is, in general, a situation of political vacuum prevailing among this informal workers’ population.

Eighth point, due to the lack of effective presence of the class-based politics, we often encounter casteist or regionalist forms of social organization among the informal/unorganized working class population. In many cases, we can see that in the absence of any revolutionary activism, these workers have organized themselves spontaneously. But the basis of this organization might appear to be caste or region if taken on the face value or superficially and no doubt these factors do play a role in this organization. But to consider it as the total reality would be a terrible mistake. In reality while on the face of it they might appear to be organized on the “non-class” basis, these workers make class as their main basis in all their activities of struggles. Geert De Neve has clearly underlined this fact in the struggle of the loom workers of Tamil Nadu.

These are some general conclusions on which we have arrived on the basis of our study of the informal/unorganized working class population. But these conclusions are the ones that are the most important and most apparent. There is a need of a detailed and intense study of the regional distribution, occupational distribution and social profile of this population. It would unearth many facts about this informal/unorganized working class population in whose light it would be easier for revolutionary organizations to work among them. But this is outside the scope of this presentation. Many such studies are ongoing even today and we would have to derive our own conclusions by critically analyzing the conclusions of these studies. As of now, on the basis of the above-mentioned some important characteristics, we can embark upon a discussion of the new strategies of organizing the informal/unorganized working class.

4. Informal/ Unorganized Working Cass: New Forms and Strategies of Organization and Resistance

On the basis of the general conclusions derived about the informal/unorganized working class in the last section of the presentation, we can now discuss briefly about the new forms and strategies of organizing them and the challenges that lie ahead. During this discussion, we would refer to some debates in which the controversy emerged on the question of the new forms and strategies (or on the question whether the informal/unorganized working class should be given so much importance in the first place), even at the cost of slightly deviating from the context. We have been clarifying our stand in these debates even earlier and we will use this opportunity to once again clarify our position on those issues.

The biggest challenge in organizing the informal/unorganized working population is the identification of the location of such an organization. The old locations for organizing the working class struggle used to be the factories or the work place in most of the cases. In today’s time, as we have seen above, capital has scattered the 93 percent portion of the working class in terms of the work place. We had mentioned about those statistics which reveal that about 80 percent of all manufacturing units of the country employ less than 50 labourers. Even in the remaining 20 percent manufacturing units which employ more than 50 labourers, most of the workers now work as ad-hoc, casual, daily wagers or contract workers.  Under such a circumstance, the work force profile of the factory is getting increasingly volatile. Consequently, the task of organizing the workers by making factory-based trade unions is getting extremely difficult. Even if such unions are somehow organized, their power is limited in most of the cases. With the labour laws becoming more and more flexible, their power has declined even further. In most of the factory struggles taking place in last two decades, the working class has faced defeat in more cases than earlier. In many cases (like during the Gorakhpur workers’ movement), even though the across-factory strong organization succeeded in bringing the State agencies to their knees, but the issues on which the labour movement began, remained more or less unsolved. In many cases, the factories whose issues were at the centre of the struggle either got closed down or the factory-owners closed them for some time and then restarted the production with an entirely new work force. Many a times such factory-owners shifted the factory from the old location to a new location with a new work force. But even in this escapist attitude it is the profit of the capital which prevails; the forces of labour certainly get political victory but struggle on the demands which have been raised do not move beyond a certain point.  And we are talking about the best possible situation which was witnessed in the Gorakhpur labour movement. In most of the cases, even this has not proved to be possible and with the full-fledged help of the administration, the factory-owners adopt repressive and arbitrary attitude towards the workers and even manage to succeed to a large extent. Prabhu Mahapatra in his above-mentioned study has stated that in the last two decades there has been a tremendous decline in the number of petitions filed in the labour courts from the side of trade unions. Other statistics also corroborate this fact. Hence, it has now become an apparent reality that along with Globalization and informalization, the graph of factory-based struggles has generally gone down as compared to the earlier period. In Gurgaon, only recently the factory-workers carried out a huge movement which shook the entire administration. But even that was not a movement organized on factory-centred issues, instead, it was an area-wide upsurge of the factory workers. When we say that the graph of the factory-based struggle has gone down, it in no way means that the factory workers are now sitting idle, have become less radical, are not fighting, ‘have become deprived of their infallible weapon of stalling the production’ etc. We only mean (neither more, nor less) that in the new times of today the old forms and strategies of the factory-workers are no longer that much effective. It is a fact independent of our will and to see this one just needs to have a look at the petitions filed in the last two decades regarding the factory-disputes or the related matters. The facts themselves narrate their own story.

In such a situation should we become hopeless or pessimistic? We assert certainly not! Definitely not! Through the correct scientific method and analysis we can convert this negative into a positive. In today’s changed circumstances we would have to go towards the bastis (working class neighbourhoods) from the factory gates and again return towards the factory gates. Before discussing this issue, we would like to indicate towards an important characteristic of the dynamics of the capitalist development in the era of Globalization. We have seen as to how the capital has disorganized the labour population at the level of the factory or work place in view of its economic and political interests. It is a fact which no one can deny today. Owing to one’s emotional hangover with the factory floor struggles one can present millions of facts and scores of example in which he/she can state that at such and such locations a huge factory is being set up even in today’s time. We would just like to tell them that surely big factories are being set up and being run at many places even today. But we would like to draw their attention to two facts. Firstly, it is not a general trend today and it needs to be determined with the data of the national level. The average size of the manufacturing units has continually decreased. Secondly, even if it is not so, the size of the factory is immaterial. The determining factor which we are talking about is not the size of the factory; that is just a corroborative fact through which we support our main argument. Even if we leave it for a moment, the main issue is informalization of the labour even within the big factories which is making the possibility of workers’ struggle at work place increasingly lesser. It is a fact today that in the last two decades the capital has continually disorganized the working class at the work place. But at the same time we would like to allude towards a second phenomenon which holds a lot of possibilities for us.

The modern capitalist development and particularly the one unfolding in the era of Globalization can never disorganize the working class at its place of residence. The model of the urban development which is inalienably attached with this model of capitalist development is bringing about the geographical concentration of the workers’ neighbourhoods on a huge scale, which is unprecedented. There are numerous Marxist/non-Marxist intellectuals like Mike Davis, Amitabh Kundu etc. who while studying the capitalist urbanization have drawn our attention towards the hitherto most expansive growth of slums and huge shanty towns. The characteristic of today’s capitalist development and urbanization is that, while it is dispersing the workers at the factory level, on the basis of the neighbourhood it is concentrating them more and more. It is not at all possible for the State to scatter the working class population on the residential basis in the entire urban landscape. It would in no way be acceptable to the social props and “sovereign consumer” of capitalism that a “brown crowd” roams around the streets of its cities and makes their “beautiful living context” as ugly. Hence, a huge structure of workers’ slum settlements can be seen around every big industrial, urban and commercial centre today. These centres are surrounded by such slum settlements and the vast turbulent ocean of workers. The labour population goes to the work from these areas and returns at the same place. This entire working population is extremely multi-faceted, multi-occupational, multi-skilled, multi-ethnic, multi-caste and multi-regional in character.

These working class neighbourhoods are extraordinary source of possibilities for the working class movement. If the ways and means of organizing these workers in their neighbourhoods can be devised, it can prove to be a way of breaking out of today’s cul de sac. Clearly any such organization of the workers would forge a more extensive class unity. Therefore the need of the hour is to build such neighbourhood-based and occupational trade unions which will organize workers employed in different trades and also unemployed workers. Such neighbourhood-based or occupational unions can organize the factory-based struggles in a new form. Besides, they will be able to struggle on the issues which will enhance the process of politicization of workers in an unprecedented way and which will be able to organize the workers as a class against the onslaught of capital in a much more effective way. Neighbourhood-based and occupational unions are two sides of the same coin. Workers of some area might organize themselves in a neighbourhood-based union, while, at the same time, being members of their respective occupational trade unions. Here neighbourhood-based unions and occupational trade unions are not two different types of bodies. Whether we see the occupational trade union or the neighbourhood-based union depends on the location of our sight, and also on the particular strategy and tactics that we have in our mind at that time. Whereas, on the one hand, the neighbourhood-based union assumes importance in defending the economic interests of the working class and in organizing it as a class against the onslaught of capital, on the other, the occupational trade unions hold the immense possibility in the future to bring to halt an entire sector, which can destablize the whole capitalist system. Neighbourhood-based trade unions can accomplish the task of bringing the capitalist class to its knees on its demands in much lesser time-span by organizing an areawide strike in an industrial area. On the other hand, an occupational trade union can organize a citywide, statewide, countrywide or even worldwide strike of a sector and bring it to standstill.

Through such unions struggle on facory-based issues also can be organized effectively. Let me illustrate this fact through an example. Suppose there is an industrial area consisting of a large number of small and medium-sized factories. Generally, the workers employed in such an industrial area live in the vicinity in slums. Now, suppose a factory-owner fires 5 workers from his factory in an unjustified manner, which employs 80 to 100 workers. The factory union struggles against this act of the factory-owner. If this struggle remains limited within the boundaries of the factory, most probably,the factory union will lose; either there will be a compromise in which the owners will be gainers, or not a single fired worker will be taken back. Now, imagine there is a neighbourhood-based union of workers in that area. This issue comes in the notice of this union and it demands the restoration of the fired workers from the factory-owner. When the owner refuses to accept this demand, the union begins an united and organized struggle of the workers of the entire industrial area and halts production in the entire area. In such a case, the organized force of labour will create a crisis for capital. Other factory-owners of the area will pressurise that factory-owner, in whose factory the dispute has arisen, to negotiate a way out and compromise with the workers. In the presence of such a neighbourhood-based union, it will become very difficult for the factory-owner to arrange new workers in sufficient numbers. Besides, since the basis of membership of such neighbourhood-based union will be residing in that area and not working in some factory, the unemployed workers of the area also will be a part of membership of the union. In such a scenario, it will be very difficult for any factory-owner to resolve the crisis in time. The presence of such a powerful neighbourhood-based union will make it possible to perform the task of picketing in the whole area in a militant way, which is not possible for a factory union of small or medium-sized factory, because they will easily be overpowered by the private hired goons of the factory-owners. However, any number of goons, howsoever large, will not be sufficient to subdue the force of a huge neighbourhood-based union. Therefore, most likely, the factory-owners will be obliged to conform to the demands of the union. We have two examples of such experiments in front of us.

The first experiment is the famous Seven Days’ Strike of 1988 of the unorganized workers of Delhi. To know about this struggle you can see the commendable research paper of Indrani Majumdar that is based on the study of this struggle. (Unorganized Workers’ Strike in Delhi, 1988, Labour in the Public Arena: Representation and Marginality, V.V.Giri National Labour Institute, NOIDA, 2004). In this paper, Indrani Majumdar has described in detail the whole process of organization of the strike, the new strategies of picketing and the ways in which the workers ran propaganda campaign. The workers did not go to factory for picketing, because this strike was organized on the basis of entire area and it would have been a waste to go to factory-gates for picketing. Therefore the picketing teams guarded opening points of all streets, alleys and roads of all industrial areas from where the workers passed. The workers ran this strike successfully till seven days and succeeded in bringing the government to its knees on most of the contentious issues.

Second example is of the Almond workers’ strike of Delhi in which thousands of workers ran a strike for 16 days in the Karawal Nagar area. This strike ended in a compromise and wages were not increased to the extent, and all the facilities were not provided, that the union had been demanding. However, despite a partial victory, a great experiment of neighbourhood-based union was carried out during this strike. During the strike, workers of nearly 70 almond workshops led a militant struggle against the almond workshop owners and 80 percent of the Karawal Nagar Almond industry had been brought to a halt. Due to some unavoidable factors, the strike was somewhat weakened during the last two days. The major reason for this was the rumour-spreading by the agents of the almond workshop owners. This strike was first of its kind for the almond workers and they did not have the experience of dealing with most of the possible situations and the workers as well as the Union leadership lacked expertise in organizing the myriad kinds of activities of a neighbourhood-based union efficiently; this led to some avoidable mistakes and lapses. Despite all this, this strike proved this fact beyond doubt that a neighbourhood-based union can paralyze an industry in an entire area. During this strike, prices of almond doubled in the dry fruit market of Delhi and this attracted the attention of national newspapers as well as national and international websites. The striking workers even took on the Police and all threats of repression failed to push them into retreat. Especially the women workers fought with indomitable courage and strength during the strike. You can refer to the report published in the January, 2010 issue of ‘Nai Samajwadi Kranti ka Udghoshak Bigul’ to understand the mixed experiences of the strike.

Apart from these, such experiments are under progress in many countries around the world and we are not the only one to think in this direction. To know more about experiments of neighbourhood-based unions and movements in other countries, see the article of Fatima Ulku Selćuk for Monthly Review (Dressing the Wound: Organizing Informal Sector Workers, May 2005, Monthly Review).

Indeed, the neighbourhood-based and occupational unions give us the opportunity to organize factory-based struggles in an even better way; however, at the same time, they also enable us to organize and politicize the workers on such issues and in such ways, that a factory-based union cannot provide. The unions organized on the basis of neighbourhood can struggle for a number of rights that are not necessarily linked to the factory, but they are very important for the working class and these demands are essentially and mainly, more political. For example, the question of housing; the right of easily available, accessible and cheap medical facilities; the right of the children of workers to education; the demand of various basic amenities in the working class neighbourhoods, such as, drinking water, electricity, sanitation system, creche for woman workers, etc. These are such demands of the working class that appear to be more like the civil rights of the workers in essence. Some comrades have this strange perception that these issues are ‘N.G.O. brand’ issues or ‘reformist’ issues! If we turn a tragic condition into a norm, then what we get is a condition of appalling irony. In other words, if today N.G.Os and voluntary organizations have snatched away the issues of such rights of the working class and are relieving the state of its burdens by raising these issues in a typical reformist fashion, and putting forward pretentious solutions of these problems through the reformist instruments of “co-operative” and self-help groups, then what we are faced with is a tragedy. These are the demands that should be raised by the revolutionary trade unions of the working class. There are a number of benefits of organizing struggle on these issues. In comparison to any economic demand, the working class population can be politicized in a much more extensive and intensive way through the struggle on these demands. These demands are quintessentially political in nature and put the entire capitalist system into the docks. These assert the claim of the working class on the citizen identity and through this act of assertion, help in exposing the reality of the capitalist ‘civil society’ in front of the working class. These unmask the whole capitalist state and society in the eyes of the working class. The process of revolutionary organization and struggle on such demands will dig the grave of N.G.O. reformism, that is contaminating the working class politics like poison. These demands will make the working class politically more conscious and powerful in every possible way. Lenin in his famous work ‘Two Tactics of Social Democracy in the Stage of Democratic Revolution’ has clearly pointed out that the proletariat should never give up its claim on the civil identity. Lenin has written that bourgeois democracy is the space in which the proletariat can practice its politics in the most extensive and intensive manner. The working class should never give up its claim on the democratic and civil rights, howsoever less, given by the bourgeois democracy in the wait of some future ‘concrete class struggle.’ That is what the bourgeoisie wants. Legally the worker is a citizen equipped with all civil and democratic rights, but in reality he/she is a secondary citizen in every practical sense. In such a scenario, if the worker himself/herself accepts this informal reality as the formal one, then it will prove to be literally suicidal.

Secondly, the civil rights for which the working class movement will struggle will have a clearly apparent class consciousness. Needless to say, these will not be petty bourgeois civil rights issues like the demand for justice for Priyadarshini Mattoo or Jessica Lal. The civil rights issues raised by us will be related to material, biological, and cultural reproduction of the workers. This thing also is not something for which we can claim novelty. If we study the charter of demands of the Chartist Movement, we will find that the damands that have been mistaken by some comrades as merely “civil rights” form a considerable part of that charter. Indeed, most of the large and political movements of the proletariat in the 19th century Europe and America had, as its main force, the working class which is called unorganized working class today and these movements had raised these so-called “civil issues” in a quite significant way. But due to the lack of a historical view and in the confusing haze created by the N.G.O. politics, some comrades have misunderstood the very demands as being reformist N.G.O. brand civil issues. If this misunderstanding is not rectified we will pay dearly for it in the future.

Before we move ahead, it is imperative to refute one more misleading perception. There is this extremely economistic and vulgar perception that by raising these demands we will shift the location of struggle from the site of production to that of consumption. Comrades plagued with this bizarre understanding forget this fundamental teaching of Marxism that in capitalist society labour power itself becomes a commodity and the location of reproduction of this commodity is the residential areas and colonies of workers. The working class will struggle for the necessary preconditions of reproduction of its life by raising these so-called “civil rights issues” like drinking water, housing, health, education etc. This will not shift the location of struggle from the site of production to “the site of consumption.” If such vulgar economistic perceptions persist, then the working class will not be left with anything else but issues of wages and allowances.

We would like to conclude this issue by arguing that we will have to organize neighbourhood-based and occupational trade unions of the working class. This in no way prohibits the possibility of organizing factory-based trade unions. We must build factory-based trade unions, wherever possible. However, even in the cases where we succeed in organizing factory-based trade unions, we will be obliged to build neighbourhood-based and occupational trade unions. Lest, through factory-based unions only, we will not be able to organize the working class as a class against the onslaught of capital in an effective manner. Occupational and neighbourhood-based unions can organize the workers on the economic and non-economic demands of much more political character, besides, obviously, the concrete economic and factory-based demands of the working class.

Indeed, the task of devising newer forms of working class struggle and resistance in the era of Globalization and informalization is quite challenging. To meet this challenge we will have to get rid of economistic, anarchist and dogmatic views of every breed; we will have to understand the changes in the modus-operendi of capitalism and also the changes in the structure and nature of the working class; we will have to decipher the novel strategies of capital against labour; without performing these tasks, we cannot innovate novel forms and strategies of working class resistance in a creative manner. Until we do not commit ourselves to this task, we cannot move towards the direction of solution of that crisis of the working class movement, that we had mentioned in the very beginning. Today an extremely important aspect of the task of making a rupture from this stagnation that is facing the working class movement of our country as well as that of the entire world, is to evolve and innovate new forms of working class resistance in the era of Globalization. And we are not the only ones to believe this.

Bibliography:

Alavi, H. et al. 1982. Capitalism and Colonial Production. London: Croom Helm.

Althusser, L. 2006. Lenin and Philosophy and Other Essays. New Delhi: Aakar Books.

Althusser, L. and Etienne Balibar. 1970. Reading ‘Capital’. London: New Left.

Amin, S. 1973. Imperialism and Unequal Development. New York: Monthly Review Press.

–. 1974. Accumulation on a World Scale. Sussex: Harvester.

Arrighi, G. 1994. The Long Twentieth Century. Money, Power and the Origins of Our Times. London: Verso.

Arrighi, G. and J.W. Moore. 2001. ‘Capitalist Development in World Historical Perspective’ In R.Albritton, M. Itoh, R. Westra and A. Zuege eds. Phases of Capitalist Development. Booms, Crises and Globalization. London: Palgrave.

Bagchi, A.K. 1982. The Political Economy of Underdevelopment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Baran, P. and P. Sweezy. 1966. Monopoly Capitalism. New York: Monthly Review Press.

Bernstein, H. 2000. “The Peasantry” in Global Capitalism: Who, Where and Why? In L. Panitach adn C.Leys eds. The Socialist Register 2001. Kolkata, K.P. Bagchi & Company.

Bernstein, H. 2008. Agrarian Questions from transition to Globalization. In H. Akrom-Lodhi and C.Kay eds. The Socialist Register 2007. London: Merlin Press.

Bottomore, T. 1991. Classes in Modern Society. London: Unwin Hyman.

Bourdieu, P. 1977. Outline of a Theory of Practice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Brass, T. 1997. Immobilised workers, footloose theory. The Journal of Peasant Studies 24, 4: 337-58.

Braverman, H. 1974. Labour and Monopoly Capitalism: The Degradation of Work in the Twentieth Century. New York: Monthly Review Press.

Breman, J. 1974. Patronage and exploitation: Changing agrarian relations in south Gujrat, India. Berkeley: University of California Press.

–1978. Seasonal migration and co-operative capitalism: Crushing of cane and of labour by sugar factories of Bardoli, Economic and Political Weekly, 13, 31-33: 1317-60.

–1985. Of Peasants, Migrants and Paupers: Rural Labour Circulation and Capitalist Production in West India. Oxford/Delhi: Clarendon Press/Oxford University Press.

–1988. The Renaissance of Social-Darwinism: Agrarian Change and Class Conflict. In G.McNicoll and M.Cain eds. Rural Development and Population: Institutions and Policy. The Population Council. New York: Oxford University Press.

–1994. Wage Hunters and Gatherers: Search for Work in the Urban and Rural Economy of South Gujrat. Delhi. Oxford University Press.

–1996. Footloose Labour: Working in India’s Informal Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

–n.d. Labour in the Informal Sector of the Economy. In V.Das, ed., The Encyclopaedia of Sociology and Social Anthropology. Delhi, Oxford University Press.

–2003. The Labouring Poor in India. Patterns of Exploitation, Subordination and Exclusion. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.

Bukharin, N. 1972. Imperialism and World Economy. New York: Monthly Review Press.

Carr, M. and M.A. Shen. 2002. Globalization and the Informal Economy: How Global Trade and Investment Impact on the Working Poor. Employment Sector 2002/1. Geneva: ILO.

Castles, S. 1997. Globalization and Migration: Some Pressing Contradiction. UNESCO, Intergovernmental Council, Keynote Address. Paris.

Chandavarkar, R.N. 1998. Imperial Power and Popular Politics: Class, Resistance and the State in India, 1950-1950. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Chandra, B. 1966. The Rise and Growth of Economic Nationalism in India: Economic Policies of Indian National Leadership, 1880-1905. New Delhi: People’s Publishing House.

Chandrashekhar, C.P. and J. Ghosh. 2000. The Market that Failed: Newliberal Economic Reforms in India. New Delhi: LeftWord Books.

Chandrashekhar, C.P. and J.B.G. Tilak eds. 2001. India‘s Socio-Economic Database: Surveys of Selected Areas. New Delhi: Tulika.

Cowen, M.P. and R.W. Shenton. 1996. Doctrines of Development. London: Routledge.

Crook, N. 1993. Labour and the Steel Towns. In P. Robb, ed., Dalit Movements and the Meanings of Labour in India. pp. 338-54. Delhi: Oxford University Press.

Das, A.N. 1983. The Indian Working Class: Relations of Production and Reproduction. In A.N.Das, V. Nilkant, and P.S. Dubey, eds. The Worker and the Working Class: A Labour Studies Anthology, pp. 161-80, Delhi: Public Enterprises Centre for Continuing Education.

Davis, M. 2001. Late Victorian Holocausts. London: Verso.

Davis, M. 2006. Planet of Slums. London: Verso.

De Haan, A. 1999. Livelihoods and Poverty: The Role of Migration – A Critical Review of the Migration Literature. Journal of Development Studies. Vol. 36, No. 2.

De Neve, G. 2005. The Everyday Politics of Labour: Working Lives in India’s Informal Sector. New Delhi: Social Science Press.

Desai, M. 2002. Marx’s Revenge: The Resurgence of Capitalism and the Death of Statist Socialism. London: Verso.

Dobb, M. 1946. Studies in the Development of Capitalism. London: Routeledge & Keagan Paul.

Engels, F. 1845. Conditions of Working Class in England. Leipzig: Otto Wiggand.

Geertz, C. 1963. Peddlers and Princes. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

Ghose, A.K. 1994. Employment in Organized Manufacturing in India. The Indian Journal of Labour Economics. Vol. 37, No.2.

Giddens, A. 1980. The Constitution of Society. Berkley: California University Press.

Goldar, B. 2000. Employment Growth in Organised Manufacturing in India. Economic and Political Weekly, April 1, pp. 1191-95.

Government of India. 1969. Report of the National Commission on Labour. New Delhi: Ministry of Labour.

–. 2002. Second National Labour Commission Report. New Delhi: Ministry of Labour.

Gorz, A. 1967. Strategy for Labour: A Radical Proposal. Boston: Beacon.

Guha-Khasnobis, Ravi Kanbur, Elinor Ostrom. 2006. eds. Linking the Formal and Informal Economy: Concepts and Policies. New York: Oxford University Press.

Gupta, Dipankar. 2003. Social Stratification: Hierarchy, Difference and Social Mobility. In Das, V. ed The Oxford India Companion to Sociology and Social Anthropology. Vol I. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.

Harris, J.R. and M.P. Todaro. 1970. Migration, Unemployment and Development: A Two Sector Analysis. American Economic Review, Vol. 60, pp. 126-42.

Harris, J. 1986. The Working Poor and the labour Aristocracy in a South Indian City: A Descriptive and Analytical Account. Modern Asian Studies 20, 2: 231-83.

Harriss-White, B. and N.Gooptu. Mapping India’s World of Unorganized Labour. Socialist Register 2001. pp. 89-118. Kolkata, K.P. Bagchi & Company.

Harriss-White, B. 2007. India‘s Socially Regulated Economy. New Delhi: Critical Quests.

–, 2004. India Working: Essays on Society and Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Hart, K. 1973. Informal Income Opportunities and Urban Employment in Ghana. Journal of Modern African Studies 11, 1: 61-89.

Hensman, R. 2001. Organizing against the odds: Women in India’s Informal Sector. Socialist Register 2001. Kolkata: K.P. Bagchi & Company.

Holmstrom, M. 1976. South Indian Factory Workers: Their Life and their World. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

–1984. Industry and Inequality: The Social Anthropology of Indian Labour. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

ILO. 2002. Decent Work and the Informal Economy. Report VI, International Labour Conference, 90th Session, International Labour Office, Geneva.

Joshi, H. and V. Joshi, 1976. Surplus Labour and the City: A Study of Bombay. Delhi: Oxford University Press.

Kapadia, K.M. and S.D. Pillai. 1972. Industrialization and Rural Society: A Study of Atul-Bulsar region. Bombay: Popular Prakashan.

Kanbur, R. 2009. Conceptualizing Informality: Regulation and Enforcement. The Indian Journal of Labour Economics. Vol. 52, Number 1, January-March.

Kannan, K.P. 2009. Dualism, Informality and Social Inequality: An Informal Economy Perspective of the Challenge of Inclusive Development in India. The Indian Jouranl of Labour Economics. Vol. 52, Number 1, January-March, 2009.

Kerr, I. 1995. Building the Railways of the Raj: 1850-1900. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.

Kundu, A. and S. Gupta. 1996. Migration, Urbanization and Regional Inequality. Economic and Political Weekly. December 28. pp. 3391-3398.

Lefebvre, H. 1991. The Production of Space. Cambridge: Blackwell.

Lenin, V.I., 1956. The Development of Capitalism in Russia. Moscow: Progress Publishers.

–, 2008. The Characterisation of Economic Romanticism. Lucknow: Rahul Foundation.

–, 2008. Imperialism: The Highest Stage of Capitalism. Lucknow: Rahul Foundation.

–, 2008. Two Tactics of Social Democracy in the Stage of Democratic Revolution. Lucknow: Rahul Foundation.

–, 1970. Proletarian Revolution and the Renegade Kautsky. Moscow: Progress Publishers.

Linebaugh, P. and M. Rediker. 2000. The Many-headed Hydra. London: Verso.

Lipietz, A. 1986. New Tendencies in the International Division of Labour: Regimes of Accumulation and Modes of Regulation. In A.K. Scott and M. Storper eds. Production, Work, Territory: The Geographical Anatomy of Industrial Capitalism. Boston: Allen & Unwin.

Marcussen, H.S. and Jens Erik Torp. 1982. Interanationalization of Capital: Prospects for the Third World. A re-examination of dependency theory. London: Zed Books.

Marx, K., 1970 Capital, Vol-I. Moscow: Progress Publishers.

–, 1978. Theories of Surplus Value, Vol-I, III. Moscow: Progress Publishers.

–, 1977. Economic and Philosophical Manuscripts. Moscow: Progress Publishers.

–, 1989. A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy. Moscow: Progress Publishers.

Marx, K. and F. Engels, Manifesto of the Communist Party (Hindi Edition) Moscow: Progress Publishers.

Massey, D. 1999. International Migration at the Dawn of the Twenty-first Century: The Role of State. Population and Development Review. pp. 303-321.

Meagher, K. 1995. Crisis, Informalization and the Urban Informal Sector in Sub-saharan Africa. Development and Change, Vol 26

Mohapatra, P. 1998. Situating the Renewal: Reflections on Labour Studies in India. Working Paper No. 2. Labour History Series. NOIDA: VVGNLI.

Mohapatra, P. 2004. Making of the Coolie: Legal construction of Labour relations in colonial India and in the Caribbean in Labour in the Public Arena , V.V. Giri National Labour institute, Noida 2004

Nagraj, R. 2004. Fall in Organized Manufacturing Employment: A Brief Note. Economic and Political Weekly. September 16, pp. 3387-90.

NCEUS. 2006. Report on Social Security for Unorganized Workers. New Delhi: GOI.

–. 2007a. Report on the Conditions of Work and Promotion of Livelihoods in the Unorganized Sector. New Delhi: GOI.

–. 2007b. Report on Financing of Enterprises in the Unorganized Sector and Creation of a National Fund for the Unorganized Sector. New Delhi: GOI.

–. 2008. Report on Definitional and Statistical Issues Relating to the Informal Economy. New Delhi: GOI.

Omvedt, G. 1981. Capitalist Agriculture and Rural Classes. Economic and Political Weekly 16, 52: Review of Agriculture, A140-A159.

Ornati, O.A. 1955. Jobs and Workers in India. Institute of International Industrial and Labour Relations. Ithaca: Conrell University Press.

Papola, T.S., P.P. Ghosh and A.N. Sharma, eds; 1993. Labour, Employment and Industrial Relations in India. Delhi: The Indian Society of Labour Economics and B.R. Publishing Corporation.

Parry, J., J. Breman, and K. Kapadia, eds., 1999. The Worlds of Indian Industrial Labour, New Delhi: Sage Publications.

Patel, B.B. 1988. Workers of Closed Mills: Patterns and Problems of their Absorption in a Metropolitan Labour Market. New Delhi: Oxford and IBH Publishing Co.

Patnaik, U. 2006. Poverty and Neo-liberalism in India. Rao Bahadur Kale Memorial Lecture delivered at Gokhale Institute of Politics and Economics, Pune, February 3.

Portes, A. and K. Hoffman. 2003. Latin American Class Structures: Their Composition and Change during the Neoliberal Era. Latin American Research Review 38 (1).

Ram, K. 1983. The Indian Working Class and the Peasantry: A Review of Current Evidence on Interlinks between the two Classes. In A.N.Das, V.Nilkant and P.S. Dubey, eds., The Worker and the Working Class: A Labour Anthology, pp. 181-86. Delhi: Public Enterprises Centre for Continuing Education.

Ramchandran, V.K. 1990. Wage Labour and Unfreedom in Agriculture: An Indian Case Study. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

Ranis and J.C.H. Fei. 1961. A Theory of Economic Development. American Economic Review. 51: 533-565.

Rogaly, B. et al. 2002. Seasonal Migration and Welfare/Illfare in Eastern India: A Social Analysis. Journal of Development Studies. 38(5).

Rudra, A. 1978. Class Relations in Indian Agriculture–I, II, III, Economic and Political Weekly, 13, 22-23, 24: 916-23, 963-68, 998-1004.

Sasikumar, S.K., ed. Special Issue on Labour Mobility, Labour and Development. Vol. 9, No. 2, December 2003. NOIDA: V.V.G.N.L.I.

Sharma, A.N. 1997. People on the Move. Delhi: Vikas Publishing House.

Sharma, R.N. 1982. Job Mobility in a Stagnant Labour Market. Indian Journal of Industrial Relations. 17, 4: 521-38.

Singh, M. 1990 The Political Economy of Unorganized Industry: A Study of the Labour Process. New Delhi: Sage Publications.

Sinha, A. 2008. Changing Patterns of Labour Migration to Delhi, 1951-2001. M.Phil Dissertation. History Department, Delhi University. Delhi: P.S.Gupta Library, Delhi University.

–2010. Rajdhani ke Mehnatkash. (Hindi) Lucknow: Rahul Foundation.

–2010. Comrade ke “katipaya buddhijeevi ya sangathan” aur comrade ka “katipaya marxvaad”. (Hindi). Bigul, June 2010.

Standing, G. 1999. Global Labour Flexibility. Seeking Distributive Justice. London: MacMillan.

Stiglitz, J. 2002. Globalization and its Discontents. London: Penguin.

Streefkerk, H. 1985. Industrial Transition in India: Artisans, Traders and Tribals in South Gujrat. Bombay: Popular Prakashan.

Thompson, E. P. 1963. The Making of the English Working Class. New York: Pantheon

Thorner, D. 1980. The Shaping of Modern India. New Delhi: Allied Publishers.

Van Der Loop, Theo. 1996. Industrial Dynamics and Fragmented Labour markets: Construction Firms and Labour Markets in India. New Delhi. Sage Publications.

Vercruijsse, E. 1984. The Penetration of Capitalism: A West African Case Study. London: Zed Books.